2023-05-31

Confucian Statecraft and Korean Institutions by James B. Palais - Ebook | Scribd

Confucian Statecraft and Korean Institutions by James B. Palais - Ebook | Scribd





See all 2 images

Read sample

Follow the Author

James B. Palais
Follow





Confucian Statecraft and Korean Institutions: Yu Hyongwon and the Late Choson Dynasty Paperback – 1 May 2014
by James B Palais (Author)
5.0 out of 5 stars 2 ratings
Part of: Korean Studies of the Henry M. Jackson School of International Studies (21 books)



See all formats and editions





Kindle
$89.21
Read with Our Free App
Hardcover
$508.00
2 New from $170.05
Paperback
$72.42
1 Used from $138.001 New from $72.42

Seventeenth-century Korea was a country in crisis--successive invasions by Hideyoshi and the Manchus had rocked the Choson dynasty (1392-1910), which already was weakened by maladministration, internecine bureaucratic factionalism, unfair taxation, concentration of wealth, military problems, and other ills. Yu Hyongwon (1622-1673, pen name, Pan'gye), a recluse scholar, responded to this time of chaos and uncertainty by writing his modestly titled Pan'gye surok (The Jottings of Pan'gye), a virtual encyclopedia of Confucian statecraft, designed to support his plan for a revived and reformed Korean system of government.

Although Yu was ignored in his own time by all but a few admirers and disciples, his ideas became prominent by the mid-eighteenth century as discussions were underway to solve problems in taxation, military service, and commercial activity. Yu has been viewed by Korean and Japanese scholars as a forerunner of modernization, but in Confucian Statecraft and Korean Institutions James B. Palais challenges this view, demonstrating that Yu was instead an outstanding example of the premodern tradition.

Palais uses Yu Hyongwon's mammoth, pivotal text to examine the development and shape of the major institutions of Choson dynasty Korea. He has included a thorough treatment of the many Chinese classical and historical texts that Yu used as well as the available Korean primary sources and Korean and Japanese secondary scholarship. Palais traces the history of each of Yu's subjects from the beginning of the dynasty and pursues developments through the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. He stresses both the classical and historical roots of Yu's reform ideas and analyzes the nature and degree of proto-capitalistic changes, such as the use of metallic currency, the introduction of wage labor into the agrarian economy, the development of unregulated commercial activity, and the appearance of industries with more differentiation of labor.

Because it contains much comparative material, Confucian Statecraft and Korean Institutions will be of interest to scholars of China and Japan, as well as to Korea specialists. It also has much to say to scholars of agrarian society, slavery, landholding systems, bureaucracy, and developing economies.

Winner of the John Whitney Hall Book Prize, sponsored by the Association for Asian Studies
Read less

Report incorrect product information.


Part of series

Korean Studies of the Henry M. Jackson School of International Studies
Print length

1288 pages
Language

English
Publisher

University of Washington Press
Publication date

1 May 2014

Product description

Review


"Marks a watershed in East Asian studies on Confucian statecraft and Korean studies on the Choson dynasty (1392 - 1910) in particular. . . . Will remain for decades to come a cornerstone of Korean Studies and required reading for specialists and students alike who are interested in Confucian statecraft and institutions in East Asia."--Journal of Asian Studies
About the Author


James B. Palais was professor of history at the University of Washington and the author of Policy and Politics in Traditional Korea.


Product details
Publisher ‏ : ‎ University of Washington Press; Reprint edition (1 May 2014)
Language ‏ : ‎ English
Paperback ‏ : ‎ 1288 pages

======
Contents 
 
Acknowledgments 
 
Introduction 
 
PART I. THE EARLY CHOSŎN DYNASTY, 1392–1650 
 
1. Confucian Statecraft in the Founding of Chosŏn 
 
2. The Disintegration of the Early Chosŏn System to 1592 
 
3. Post-Imjin Developments in Military Defense and the Economy 
 
PART II. SOCIAL REFORM: YANGBAN AND SLAVES 
 
Introduction 
 
4. Remolding the Ruling Class through Education and Schools 
 
5. New Schools: Conservative Restraints on Radicalism 
 
6. Slavery: The Slow Path to Abolition 
 
Conclusion 
 
PART III. LAND REFORM 
 
Introduction 
 
7. Land Reform: Compromises with the Well-Field Model 
 
8. Redistributing Wealth through Land Reform 
 
9. Late Chosŏn Land Reform Proposals 
 
Conclusion 
 
PART IV. MILITARY REFORM 
 
Introduction 
 
10. The Royal Division Model: Rotating Duty Soldiers and Support Taxpayers 
 
11. The Debate over the Military Training Agency, 1651–82 
 
12. The Search for Alternative Modes of Military Finance 
 
13. Military Reorganization, Weapons, and Walls 
 
14. The Military Service System, 1682–1870 
 
Conclusion 
 
PART V. REFORM OF GOVERNMENT ORGANIZATION 
 
Introduction 
 
15. The King and His Court 
 
16. Reforming the Central Bureaucracy 
 
17. Personnel Policy 
 
18. Provincial and Local Administration 
 
19. The Community Compact System (Hyangyak) 
 
20. Yu Hyŏngwŏn's Community Compact Regulations 
 
Conclusion 
 
PART VI. FINANCIAL REFORM AND THE ECONOMY 
 
Introduction 
 
21. Tribute and the Taedong Reform 
 
22. The Taedong Model for Official Salaries and Expenses 
 
23. Copper Cash and the Monetary System 
 
24. Yu Hyŏngwŏn's Analysis of Currency 
 
25. A Cycle of Inflation and Deflation 
 
26. Cash and Economic Change after 1731 
 
Conclusion 
 
Epilogue: The Complexities of Korean Confucian Statecraft 
 
Notes 
 
Glossary 
 
List of Kings of the Chosŏn Dynasty 
 
List of Names

======
Ebook2,362 pages39 hours
Confucian Statecraft and Korean Institutions: Yu Hyongwon and the Late Choson DynastyShow full title


By James B. Palais
Rating: 4 out of 5 stars

4/5

(1 rating)


Included in your subscription

About this ebook


Seventeenth-century Korea was a country in crisis successive invasions by Hideyoshi and the Manchus had rocked the Choson dynasty (1392-1910), which already was weakened by maladministration, internecine bureaucratic factionalism, unfair taxation, concentration of wealth, military problems, and other ills. Yu Hyongwon (1622 1673, pen name, Pan gye), a recluse scholar, responded to this time of chaos and uncertainty by writing his modestly titled Pan gye surok (The Jottings of Pan gye), a virtual encyclopedia of Confucian statecraft, designed to support his plan for a revived and reformed Korean system of government.

Although Yu was ignored in his own time by all but a few admirers and disciples, his ideas became prominent by the mid-eighteenth century as discussions were underway to solve problems in taxation, military service, and commercial activity. Yu has been viewed by Korean and Japanese scholars as a forerunner of modernization, but in Confucian Statecraft and Korean Institutions James B. Palais challenges this view, demonstrating that Yu was instead an outstanding example of the premodern tradition.

Palais uses Yu Hyongwon s mammoth, pivotal text to examine the development and shape of the major institutions of Choson dynasty Korea. He has included a thorough treatment of the many Chinese classical and historical texts that Yu used as well as the available Korean primary sources and Korean and Japanese secondary scholarship. Palais traces the history of each of Yu s subjects from the beginning of the dynasty and pursues developments through the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. He stresses both the classical and historical roots of Yu s reform ideas and analyzes the nature and degree of proto-capitalistic changes, such as the use of metallic currency, the introduction of wage labor into the agrarian economy, the development of unregulated commercial activity, and the appearance of industries with more differentiation of labor.

Because it contains much comparative material, Confucian Statecraft and Korean Institutions will be of interest to scholars of China and Japan, as well as to Korea specialists. It also has much to say to scholars of agrarian society, slavery, landholding systems, bureaucracy, and developing economies.

Winner of the John Whitney Hall Book Prize, sponsored by the Association for Asian Studies
Skip carousel



LanguageEnglish
PublisherUniversity of Washington Press
Release dateApr 28, 2015



=====
Introduction 
 
Since liberation from Japanese colonial rule in 1945 Korean historians have been waging a mighty struggle to rid themselves of the 
burden of Japanese colonial historiography, which decreed that for the five hundred years of the Chosŏn (Yi) dynasty (1392–1910) Korea 
was mired in stagnation and incapable of development and progress. In the last few years this struggle has been won because the 
efforts of Korean historians have shown that Korea appeared to be caught up in significant changes in its social structure, economy, 
and other important institutions, particularly after emerging from the disaster inflicted on the Korean people by the marauding armies of 
Hideyoshi Toyotomi between 1592 and 1598. 
Despite the success in demonstrating that change rather than stasis is a better way of understanding the flow of history in the latter 
Chosŏn dynasty, the interpretation of the nature of that change has not been as successful. In crude outline the essential argument 
about the nature of change was that the rigid social structure of the early Chosŏn period, often described as “feudal,” had been 
disrupted and opened to greater upward and downward social mobility, and that the primary cause of social change consisted of the 
growth of the market and the liberalization of the economy. Economic liberalization flowed from the increase not only in agricultural 
production, but also in per capita productivity and the creation of a surplus over subsistence gained through developments in 
agricultural technology and methods. There was, in addition, the creation of a new class of entrepreneurial farmers seeking to maximize 
production and wealth, expansion of the marketing of the agricultural surplus, development of handicraft industry and an increase in 
the division of labor, and the intrusion of private merchants into the privileges and profits of state-licensed merchant monopolies. 
These economic developments showed signs of a transition toward capitalism, particularly in the partial monetization of the economy 
after 1608, the growth of private merchant activity and the accumulation of commercial capital, the development of private enterprise in 
cotton textiles, ginseng cultivation, mining, pottery, and metallurgy, and increased division of labor in minting, mining, and ceramics. 
These changes were allegedly accompanied by a shift from “feudal” relations between landlords and tenants and slaveholders and 
slaves. Commoner tenants as well as slaves were subjected to demands on their labor as well as payment of rent to a system of 
contractual, short-term sharecropping and hired labor. There was a rapid decline in the slave population from about one-third to less 
than one-tenth of the population after 1780–1800. As the line between slaves and commoners began to disappear, so too did the 
dividing line between the semiaristocratic yangban and commoners dissolve as the new entrepreneurial peasants accumulated wealth 
and pushed their way into the upper echelons of society. 
More recently, a number of scholars have been associating these developments with a virtual rise of the masses (minjung) and a 
higher level of national consciousness. In contemporary historiography the masses have become the most important factor in 
explaining the surge of dynamism in the late Chosŏn period and the drive toward modernity and capitalism in the economy. There is 
heightened awareness of Korea as an independent nation in contradistinction to the universalistic moral philosophy of Confucianism 
and the subordination of nationality and independence to the dependence, if not subservience, of Korea to Chinese imperial authority. 
These revisionist interpretations of the history of the late Chosŏn dynasty have been consciously designed not only to prove the 
existence of dynamism and development, but also to counteract the previous emphasis on political history and the actions of the 
educated yangban class at the top of the political structure. The focus of more recent historians has been the activities of the previously 
neglected mass of the people, who failed to leave much of a written record of their lives because the educated elite monopolized the use 
of writing. 
The contribution of the new Korean historiography to our understanding of Korean history has been valuable by uncovering very 
important, but previously unnoticed, trends in the economy. What is needed at this stage, however, is to restore some balance by 
examining the ideas and policies of the educated officials and statecraft writers of the time, who were attempting to analyze the 
problems of society and devise solutions for them. Their efforts are of invaluable aid in understanding the nature of Korean society and 
the changes it was experiencing in the last half of the dynasty. 
 
YU HYŎNGWŎN’S PAN’GYE SUROK 
 
There are a number of ways by which the current wisdom of the changes that occurred in the late Chosŏn dynasty could be studied, but 
it is my belief that a useful beginning could be made by analyzing what was probably the greatest piece of writing on the problems of 
statecraft in Korean history up to the time of its composition. That work is the Pan’gye surok (A miscellaneous account of the man from 
Pan’gye), written by the scholar-recluse, Yu Hyŏngwŏn, probably between 1652 and 1670. Born in 1622 to a yangban family of officials, 
Yu made two brief but desultory attempts at the civil service examinations, but he gave up on the prospect of an official career and 
chose to spend the rest of his life in scholarly contemplation and writing. 
Yu’s work is especially valuable for our understanding of the late Chosŏn period because he was living through the beginnings of 
the changes described above, and he wrote with great clarity and detail on what he perceived to be the major problems facing the 
country. Yu has been portrayed by contemporary historians as one of the first, if not the foremost, of a new school of scholars of 
Practical Learning (Sirhak) who turned their attention away from earlier concerns with Confucian ethics and metaphysics to the 
problems of statecraft. The first scholar to study Yu’s work after liberation in 1945 was Ch’ŏn Kwan’u, who even regarded Yu’s work and 
the Sirhak movement as a whole as reflecting the trend toward modernity and nationalism that characterized the late Chosŏn period.¹ 
One of the tasks of this book will be to revise that interpretation, but its ultimate goal will be to transcend the interpretation of 
Confucian statecraft in isolation from surrounding historical circumstance. I will discuss the nature of the major changes taking place in 
Korean society throughout the Chosŏn dynasty from 1392 to the conclusion of the Kanghwa Treaty in 1876 to assess the relationship 
between scholarly statecraft thought and historical reality and the influence that each had on the other. 
 
CONFUCIAN STATECRAFT THOUGHT IN THE CHOSŎN PERIOD 
 
The Chosŏn dynasty has been generally known as the age of Confucianism in Korean history, not because Confucian thought was not 
important in Korea prior to 1392, but because Confucianism played a secondary role to Buddhism and native modes of social and family 
organization. After 1392 the Neo-Confucian thought of Sung dynasty China as epitomized in the writings of Chu Hsi in the twelfth 
century became the basis not only of the educational curriculum and the civil service examination system, but also of ritual practice, 
family organization, and ethical values for an increasing percentage of Korean society. Neo-Confucian beliefs, norms, and practices may 
have taken two to three hundred years to permeate the lowest levels of village life, although during that time other beliefs like 
Buddhism, Taoism, shamanism, and geomancy were preserved, especially among the uneducated peasants. Eventually the 
Neo-Confucians dominated Korean society and thought even though they may not have been able to convert everyone to all their beliefs 
and practices. 
The Neo-Confucian ideologues who participated in the founding of the Chosŏn dynasty in 1392 played an important role in carrying 
many features of the Confucian statecraft program into effect. Since a number of institutions were introduced or strengthened at their 
insistence, it was clear that the early Chosŏn period represented the zenith of the influence of Confucian statecraft ideas on practical 
administration. A strange development ensued thereafter, however. The influence of Confucian statecraft scholars outside the 
bureaucracy on public policy waned almost to the point of extinction. Since all active officials in the regular bureaucracy of the Chosŏn 
dynasty were certified through the civil service examinations as orthodox believers in the Neo-Confucian canon, there could be no clear 
accusation that the regime was failing to live up to its obligation to respect Confucian principles of governance. Active officials, 
however, were subjected to the debilitating effects of routinization, neglect, and even corruption as well as lingering practices and 
institutions carried over from the Koryŏ dynasty without Confucian rectification. 
Furthermore, scholarly interest among Korean Confucians had gravitated away from the initial stress on an unsophisticated 
conversion of the benighted masses from Buddhism, animism, and other “barbaric” tendencies to the knowledge and practice of lives 
governed by Confucian ethical and social principles. The stress on tutelage of the unenlightened shifted by the sixteenth century to a 
more sophisticated concern with the interpretation of the abstruse metaphysics associated with fundamental cosmic principles and the 
rectification of the mind’s proclivity for immoral, unethical, and antisocial actions. But as the major concern of Confucian scholars 
shifted to an inner struggle for the correct understanding of the mind’s relation to pure cosmic principle, contemplation and writing on 
problems of statecraft faded as a subject of scholarly interest. For the Neo-Confucian ethicist, good government was simply a problem 
of the moral conversion of sinners to saints, to borrow a Christian phrase, not the manipulation of institutions, which was left to active 
officials to work out in practical affairs. To draw another analogy with the twentieth-century West, the relationship of statecraft thought 
to ethical metaphysics was analogous to the relationship between applied and pure science; the former was useful and practical but less 
respected than the latter, which dealt with fundamental truths. 
For those reasons, the initiative for institutional reform came in the middle of the sixteenth century from active officials after the 
serious deterioration of many institutions had run its course. Those initiatives were taken by men like Yulgok (the ho or pen name of Yi 
I), Cho Hŏn, and Yu Sŏngnyŏng, who provided the impetus for others like Kim Yuk to sustain an institutional reform movement that 
carried over into the seventeenth century. A few scholars out of office as well then began to shift their attention to matters of statecraft 
and institutional reform after 1600, but it was not until 1650 or so that Yu Hyŏngwŏn embarked on an effort that would consume the 
rest of his scholarly life. That effort was to lay out the fundamental principles for institutional reform based on traditions hallowed by 
Confucian scholars and officials back to the age of antiquity in China. 
 
YU HYŎNGWŎN’S ROLE 
 
The Seventeenth-Century Situation 
 
Unfortunately, the seventeenth-century situation contrasted markedly from the transition from the Koryŏ to Chosŏn dynasties in the late 
fourteenth century. The opportunity for Yu Hyŏngwŏn’s message to be heard by the king and bureaucrats at court, who were already 
Confucian in belief and practice, was nonexistent. The channels of communication between rusticated scholars and the central 
bureaucrats were closed off and amateur advice on matters of statecraft was held in low esteem. 
This phenomenon was not the sole fault of the exclusive right of privileged communication with the throne by regular members of 
the bureaucracy who had sought to block opportunities for access for nonofficials to elevate their own prestige. Fault also lay in the 
hereditary factionalism that had emerged in Korea after 1575 and served to further narrow access to the king. This was undoubtedly the 
problem with Yu himself since he was a bona fide member of the yangban Munhwa Yu clan living in Seoul. His father and grandfather 
had held office, he had a prestigious ancestor in Yu Kwan who associated with Cho Kwangjo’s disciples in the early sixteenth century, 
and his mother was the daughter of a high official in the Yŏju Yi clan. His wife was from the P’ungsan Sim clan, and her father, Sim 
Sugyŏng, was a minister of the right – all of which should have qualified him as a social equal of officeholding yangban. Unfortunately, 
his father, a member of the Northerner (Pug’in) faction associated with King Kwanghaegun, suffered disaster when the Westerner 
faction (Sŏin) deposed the king and replaced him with King Injo in 1623. That same year his father was implicated in a plot to restore 
Kwanghaegun to the throne and was killed during interrogation under torture. Thereafter, the Northerners were excluded from 
opportunities for important bureaucratic posts. 
Yu passed the chinsa examination, but abandoned all interest in pursuing a higher degree or an official post. He formed associations 
with members of factions out of power and was known by leaders of the Southerner faction (Nam’in) like Yun Hyu and Hŏ Mok, who 
had their heyday from 1689 to 1694, and were later purged from power for a hundred years until King Chŏngjo restored some of them to 
the government in the late eighteenth century. Yu spent most of his life as a recluse in the district of Puan in Chŏlla Province, where in 
1652 he began work on his magnum opus, the Pan’gye surok. He finished it nineteen years later in 1670, only three years before his 
death. It is one of only three of his twenty known works that remain, the other two include his recently discovered survey history of 
Korea in the format used by Chu Hsi himself for China and recently compiled short fragments. He wrote treatises on Neo-Confucian 
metaphysics, a synopsis of Chu Hsi’s writings, a Korean geography, a study of the Chinese pronunciation of Chinese characters, works 
on military affairs and methods, and other studies of prose and poetry, medicine and acupuncture.² 
Some have argued that factional exclusion and the rustication of members of minority factions were, in fact, the phenomena that 
created the great scholars of practical affairs like Yu Hyŏngwŏn, but even if that were true, it did not serve to provide an audience for 
their ideas at court. The transmission of Yu’s ideas was confined to his descendants, disciples, and intellectual heirs outside the 
bureaucracy until the middle of the eighteenth century when they began to affect some active officials who cited his proposals during 
the debate over the equal-service reform (kyunyŏkpŏb). 
Yu’s magnum opus, the Pan’gye surok, was not well known while he was alive, and it did not attract King Sukchong’s interest when 
Pae Sanggyu recommended it to him in 1678. It was presented by No Sahyo and other scholars and degree holders to Sukchong again 
in 1694, but again without stirring the king’s interest. It was known and admired by the statecraft scholar, Yi Ik, of the early eighteenth 
century and by Yi’s disciple, An Chŏngbok of the late eighteenth. The text itself was made known to the court as early as 1678, and 
recommended to King Yŏngjo by a former royal secretary, Yang Tŭkchung, in 1741. Yŏngjo almost authorized its printing in 1750, but 
postponed the decision until 1769, although he permitted only three copies to be made and had them stored at the Namhan Mountain 
fortress and in the Historical Repository.³ In 1770 he authorized the governor of Kyŏngsang Province to begin work on a wood-block 
edition. One cannot be sure from the history of its publication just how well known its contents were, and it appears that until 
publication of the final work in twenty-six kwŏn in 1770, a shorter version of only thirteen kwŏn lacking the chapters on Chinese sources 
was more widely circulated.⁴ 
In 1770 Yŏngjo also authorized Hong Ponghan to supervise the compilation of an encyclopedia of laws and institutions modeled 
after the Wen-hsien t’ung-k’ao of Ma Tuan-lin. This first edition contained no references to Yu’s work, but King Chŏngjo, who was 
dissatisfied with the errors and omissions in it, authorized Yi Man’un to undertake a second enlarged edition that included statements 
by Yu and others known to have read his work. Although the second edition was completed in 1782, it was not published in type until 
1908, which may have restricted the spread of Yu’s ideas. Nevertheless, Yu’s work had to have been known to the most prestigious 
scholar-officials at court, if not the country as a whole.⁵ When the Taewongun undertook a series of reforms in the 1860s, however, Yu’s 
ideas, and those of the statecraft writers of the eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries, were reflected in many of the policies adopted. 
Therefore, the institutional reforms of the late Chosŏn dynasty got under way before Yu began writing on those questions, and an 
even longer lapse, three quarters of a century, occurred before his own statecraft views became known to the court and the educated 
public. For those reasons this book will attempt to survey the developments that were taking place before, during, and after Yu’s life to 
compare his ideas with the reform proposals raised and solutions reached without benefit of his advice and wisdom. This exercise will 
not consist simply of a comparison of two unconnected bodies of thought, because Yu himself was influenced by the ideas and actions 
of government officials from the late sixteenth century to the end of his life in 1672. It will thus be possible to trace the direction of 
influence and the degree of intercommunication in the transmission of ideas, and the separation between active officials and armchair 
scholars on the leading institutional issues of the day. 
Discussing the writings of an armchair scholar when his work was unknown to men who counted in government affairs, let alone 
the public at large, might appear to some as a futile, antiquarian exercise with no relevance to the understanding of real history. Some 
might even regard a study of an armchair Confucian writer as a waste of time with only the marginal utility of revealing the views of an 
single idealist. The best defense against this charge is that Yu Hyŏngwŏn did what contemporary historians and social scientists do – 
and what contemporary politicians cannot do – he provided a detailed study of the history of institutions from their origin and 
development throughout three millennia of Chinese as well as Korean history, and a lively discussion of the views of leading officials 
and statecraft scholars for overcoming the problems of those institutions. Whether one agrees or disagrees with Yu’s own 
recommendations for reform, he provided what was truly an epochal and pioneering study of the institutions of his time that was far 
more valuable and enlightening than the usual recitation of eternal and universal Confucian moralistic verities that peppers the oft too 
brief and vague memorials of thousands of active officials. 
 
Rationality and Empiricism within the Confucian Tradition 
 
In the twentieth century, Yu, along with other members of the Sirhak or practical learning group, have been described variously by 
scholars as the harbingers of modernity because in their investigation of the problems of real life and the real world they seemed to 
presage the beginnings of a materialist rejection of Confucian moral idealism. In their use of reason and empirical observation as a 
means of questioning the standards of their time they seemed to threaten the solid unity of fact and value enshrined in holistic 
Confucian philosophy. In their awareness of Korean uniqueness and national identity they appeared to pose a threat to universal and 
cosmopolitan Confucian culture. In their concern for the welfare of the common man they suggested a populist attack on hereditary 
privilege, and in their desire for wealth and power they threatened to break the stranglehold of Confucian physiocracy and unleash the 
forces of production and the market. 
As this study will reveal, however, these generalizations about Sirhak thought are misleading half-truths, often the product of an 
anachronistic misreading of the essence of Confucian statecraft in terms of modern, Western categories of positivistic science. Where 
rationality and empirical method is discovered, it is usually interpreted as a sign of modernity, when in fact traditional premodern or 
nonscientific Confucianism could be quite rational and even empirical in its approach to problem solving in the art of government. But 
Confucian rationality and empiricism were not based on a rigorous epistemology. Confucian thinkers could move with ease from blind 
dogmatic faith in the virtually holy writ of the ancient Chinese classics to a critical use of reason in attacking the anomalies of 
contemporary society and back again with hardly a hint of remorse over any logical contradiction. 
Nevertheless, what was certainly lacking was an exaltation of reason as a criterion of knowledge higher than the bequeathed wisdom 
of the classics. Nor is there to be found in Yu’s writings any suggestion that sense data are the only reliable sources of information or 
knowledge such that a new political science could be created independent of the maxims of Confucian wisdom. Yu’s statecraft never 
separated the facts of sensual experience from the moral truths of Confucianism and never treated the facts of human society separately 
from the underlying cosmological principles that inhere in the universe. Yu was always a Confucian in morals and philosophy, holistic 
in his fusing of moral truth and empirical knowledge. Thus to separate the rational and empirical elements of his thought from the total 
context of his philosophical understanding of the world is to do violence to the comprehensive nature of the Confucian world view. 
 
Yu’s Historical-Mindedness 
 
Yu Hyŏngwŏn’s significance as a statecraft thinker is not to be found in the creation of new and independent theories of government 
and politics. He believed, as most Confucians, that the greatest wisdom was the product of the Chinese sages of antiquity and that the 
models of government institutions were to be found in the san-tai period in Chinese history, the age of the three dynasties of Hsia, 
Shang, and Chou. Yu did not believe it was possible to improve on the wisdom of the sages and he did not have the temerity to 
presume that he could attain, let alone surpass, their creative genius. The task for him was to identify and extract the fundamental 
principles of government theory and institutional practice as used in ancient times and adapt it to the quite different historical and 
social circumstances of seventeenth-century Korea. His acknowledgment of the necessity of adaptation meant, of course, that his own 
hopes for creating the best possible society would always be less than ideal, that Utopian aspirations would always be constrained by 
the contingency of existing social and historical circumstances. The fascinating aspect of his thought is to be found rather in his 
working out of compromise positions between the ideal and the real, revealing in the process that his realization of the impossibility of 
total restoration of the world of the ancient sages forced frequent pragmatic compromises. 
Kim Chunsŏk in a recent study has drawn similar conclusions. He agrees that Yu was not a Restorationist despite his admiration for 
sage antiquity, and that he acknowledged the need to adjust principle to contemporary circumstance. Kim also held that Yu regarded 
almost all institutions in the period of the “later age” (huse) after the fall of the Chou dynasty, including the statutes of the early Chosŏn 
law code, the Kyŏngguk taejŏn, as immoral, corrupted, and deserving of reform, if not abolition. In my view, however, Kim’s conclusion 
derives from his concentration only on Yu’s land reform proposals and not consideration of other issues like military and other 
reforms, which reveal a surprising willingness to accept some of the early Chosŏn institutions and restore them to their pristine form. 
Yu’s attitude toward the past and his sometimes pragmatic compromise with current reality pose a far more complex problem than Kim 
was willing to allow.⁶ 
 
Igi Debate and Sirhak: Idealism and Materialism 
 
Some scholars have attempted to connect the writers of the sirhak group with one of the two bipolar alternatives in the philosophical 
debate over the primacy of either principle or material force (igi) in the composition of the cosmos and the human mind. Principle was 
defined in the Neo-Confucian lexicon as the “ought” as well as the “is” of existence, why things are both what they are and what they 
ought to be.⁷ Material force represented the material component of all objects, but since the mind had no observable materiality, it 
could not have been matter in the common sense of the term. For that reason Hoyt Tillman employed “psycho-physical energy” and 
Wing-tsit Chan used “material force” to represent it.⁸ 
Although principle and psycho-physical energy (igi) were supposed to be inseparable parts of a duality according to Chu Hsi’s 
formulation, Korean scholars in the sixteenth century debated whether abstract and ideal principles or the materiality of objects and the 
human mind really governed the operation of the human psyche and human behavior. Although almost all the sixteenth-century 
participants in the debate agreed on the notion that principle and psycho-physical energy were mixed together or intertwined, their 
disciples and descendants began to create a polarity in the debate and take sides, unfortunately mostly (but not exclusively) along the 
lines of the political factions that formed after 1575. For that matter, preference for psycho-physical energy had already occurred in the 
writings of Chang Tsai in the Sung dynasty, which was picked up by Sŏ Kyŏngdŏk (pen name, Hwadam, 1489–1546) and Na Hŭnsin 
(pen name, Chŏng’am, 1465–1547) in Korea in the previous century. 
In any case, it was not the divergent interpretations of principle and psycho-physical energy of the two most illustrious 
scholar-officials of the sixteenth century – Yi Hwang (pen name, T’oegye) and Yi I (pen name, Yulgok) – who triggered the rivalry, but 
the followers (emphasis mine) and intellectual heirs of those men. The disciples of T’oegye were generally known as advocates of the 
primacy of principle, and those of Yulgok as proponents of psycho-physical energy. The attempt by some twentieth-century scholars to 
link these two alternatives to the Western dichotomy between idealism and materialism and then identify statecraft writers with 
material-force monism and Western materialism has not proved convincing. Yu himself was certainly no materialist, and to the end of 
his life he became an advocate of the supremacy of principle. 
The summary of his ideas about principle and psycho-physical energy in the brief biography written by An Chŏngbok of the late 
eighteenth century indicates that Yu insisted strongly on the monism of fundamental cosmic and metaphysical reality and claimed that 
principle and psycho-physical energy were never separated from each other despite arguments of other philosophers to the contrary.⁹ 
This idea has been further explored recently by Yi Usŏng and Kim Chunsŏk, who have studied the recently published collection of his 
writings on miscellaneous issues and other materials.¹⁰ Yi found in a letter Yu wrote to Chang Tongjik at the age of thirty-seven se that 
he was inclined to favor the notion that psycho-physical energy took primacy over principle because he could not imagine how principle 
could even exist in the absence of psycho-physical energy since principle had no materiality to it. A decade later, however, at the age of 
forty-eight se he changed his mind and declared that both principle and psycho-physical energy existed together and were intermixed 
with one another, and that principle did not owe its existence to psycho-physical energy. 
He rejected Yulgok’s view that principle and psycho-physical energy “issued forth” or made their appearance jointly. He preferred to 
think of the “mind of Heaven” (ch’ŏnsim, the equivalent of principle in the world) as always a part of “the mind of man” (insim, the 
equivalent of the imperfect human mind beclouded by the psycho-physical energy within it) and never separated from it. But this did 
not mean that he automatically adopted that position because he had decided to follow T’oegye. On the contrary, he also thought that 
T’oegye’s perception of the igi relationship, that “when principle emerges, psycho-physical energy follows it, and when psycho-physical 
energy emerges, principle rides on it” was too suggestive of dualism, connoting the possibility of separation between moral principles 
and the inert materiality in which it inheres. 
Instead, he worked out his own formulation, that principle and psycho-physical energy were “never separated” and that principle, or 
moral principles, often referred to as the “mind of the Way” (tosim, equivalent to the mind of Heaven) was also to be found in the mind 
of man, which was vulnerable to human desire and corruption. Yi Usŏng suggested that he probably received some inspiration for this 
viewpoint from the first important statecraft scholar of the seventeenth century, Han Paekkyŏm. Han’s essay on “The Four Origins and 
Seven Emotions” (sadan ch’ilchŏng), rejected Yulgok’s view that moral principles in the mind (the four origins) were produced by the 
mind of Heaven, while the source of the seven emotions (i.e., impure feelings and desires rather than pure virtue) was the mind of man. 
Han’s correction to this formulation was that psycho-physical energy was responsible for the emergence (of both), but that principle 
was to be understood as the reason why anything (i.e., psycho-physical energy) emerged or appeared in the world at all – a position that 
at once refuted both Yulgok’s and T’oegye’s positions. 
Yu reinforced his preference for principle by making the conventional argument that principle was to be found in everything in the 
universe, but he emphasized not only things and events, but in particular the laws and institutions of the real world, which he had 
chosen to be the objects of his own study. He called his version of principle, “real principle” (silli), and the object of his study “real 
facts” (silsa). Yi Usŏng wrote that Yu’s shift to a position close to principle-monism meant that his objective was now to determine what 
Heaven’s principle (ch’ŏlli) was with respect to institutions, an exercise completely free from any utilitarian objective.¹¹ 
Kim Chunsŏk expanded on Yi’s analysis by pursuing Yu’s formulations on what he thought was Yu’s creation of a new philosophical 
basis for his statecraft study based on a critical evaluation of the views of Chinese and Korean scholars since Chu Hsi. Kim held that Yu 
did not simply follow everything written by Chu Hsi, but went back to the classics and used his own independent reason to choose 
among alternative formulations, a scholarly method that he applied as well to his study of institutions and laws. Kim calls the method 
one of “critical verification based on the citation of evidence” (pip’anjŏg’imyŏ silchŭng [chŏn’gŏ] juŭijŏg’in hangmun t’aedo).¹² Kim’s 
formulation is an interesting one, and it will be kept in mind as we analyze Yu’s writings on Chosŏn institutions. 
Kim chose to emphasize the contribution Yu made to the establishment of a philosophical justification for the study of the real 
world and “real facts” (silsa) by introducing a new term, “real principle” (silli), which he defined as a monistic entity in which 
psycho-physical energy was included and subordinated to it. Since real principle was to him the essential feature of the universe, he 
stated that he would not be looking for laws of movement and action totally divorced from moral principles because those principles 
were an inseparable component of that world. 
Yu extended his notion of real principle to all aspects of Confucian philosophical debate, in which principle was equivalent to the 
Great Ultimate (t’aegŭk), Heaven (Ch’ŏn) or Heaven’s principle (Ch’ŏlli), the Way (to), the mind of the Way (tosim), human nature 
(sŏng), the four basic virtues in the human mind (sadan), and the idea of sincerity (sŏng, or being true to one’s self) in the Doctrine of the 
Mean. In his formulation, however, real principle was not an equal partner with all those concepts that had been regarded as antithetical 
to the elements in the above list – the corruptible mind of Man (insim), psycho-physical energy (ki), the human emotions (chŏng), the 
seven emotions (ch’ilchŏng), and human desires. On the contrary, all of them were part of the unity that pervaded all of the world and 
humanity in which real principle was an irremovable part. Kim argued that the contribution of this formulation to those who came after 
Yu, men like Yi Ik and Tasan (Chŏng Yagyong), was that they rejected the whole igi debate for its fundamental misunderstanding of the 
unity in the cosmos and its creation of an unnecessary dualism that only reinforced factional strife.¹³ 
These new studies by Yi Usŏng and Kim Chunsŏk confirm my conviction that Yu’s unitarian world view was based on his concept of 
the interconnectedness of moral principles and the mundane affairs of government and the real world, and that he was the last person 
one might expect would launch the separation of fact from value that supposedly marked the beginning of objective and empirical 
reason and empirical observation and its divorce from Christian revelation and faith in the Renaissance.¹⁴ 
 
THE CONFUCIAN FRAMEWORK OF STATECRAFT DEBATES 
 
Almost all the participants in the debate over institutional reform in late Chosŏn were card-carrying believers in Confucianism, just as 
Yu was. Despite the current enthusiasm for Yu and other so-called sirhak scholars of practical learning because of the misperception 
that they were leading the way out of traditional Confucianism towards some form of “modernity,” the dialogue was limited to 
Confucian alternatives alone until Christian heterodoxy intruded on the Korean scene in the late eighteenth century. And even then, the 
vigorous persecution of Christianity in 1791 and 1801 drove the potential for ideological disruption at the highest level of government 
underground, restoring the spectrum of acceptable alternatives once again to the Confucian framework. 
Nonetheless, working within the Confucian framework did not mean conformity only to a single ideal or a single solution of 
contemporary problems. At the least, Yu’s work represented a rejection of several aspects of the status quo in Chosŏn life, which most 
Confucian scholars and officials at the time defended as proper or rationalized as legitimate. His statecraft scholarship also marked 
both a resurgence of a reform movement that had begun in official circles in the late sixteenth century, and a shift to matters of 
statecraft and institutional reform by scholars outside the Korean capital and bureaucracy. 
Whether the role of Confucian statecraft thought was to safeguard the status quo or demand change depended on the 
circumstances involved. In crude terms, Korean Confucian statecraft was most reformist at the beginning of the Chosŏn dynasty in the 
late fourteenth through mid-fifteenth centuries, again in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries in response to the routinization of 
government institutions and bureaucracy, and finally after the imsul peasant rebellion of 1862. In between, the tide of Confucian 
statecraft thought reverted to a conservative mentality dedicated to the preservation of the status quo and stability. 
 
EARLY CHOSŎN INSTITUTIONS AND THEIR DEGENERATION 
 
Early Chosŏn Institutions 
 
Since Yu’s thought represented that second wave of reform and his writings were geared to the problems of the Chosŏn dynasty at its 
midpoint, and not at its creation, it is essential that the reader should understand the reasons why his reform program did not simply 
replicate all the proposals of the late Koryŏ reformers. For that reason, Part 1 of this book will consist of a lengthy background section 
consisting of three chapters devoted to the institutional makeup of the early Chosŏn dynasty (chap. 1), the deterioration of those early 
Chosŏn institutions up to and including the devastating effects of Hideyoshi’s invasion in the 1590s (chap. 2), and the nature of the 
recovery and institutional reconstruction that was undertaken in the half-century prior to the beginning of Yu’s two-decade long study in 
1650 (chap. 3). 
The description of the institutions of the early Chosŏn dynasty is essential because the essence of Yu Hyŏngwŏn’s critique, based 
on his own Confucian perspective on institutional questions, was that the institutions adopted at the beginning of the dynasty were not 
fully informed by the proper Confucian spirit. Part of his reasoning for this was that those institutions were not created according to the 
proposals made by the most thoroughgoing Confucian reformers of the transition period (particularly land reform). The incomplete 
Confucianization of early Chosŏn institutions was caused either by unavoidable circumstance or by the different, nonideological 
perspective of the dynastic founder, Yi Sŏnggye, who was a military commander and politician rather than a philosopher or moralist. 
His second reason was that the late Koryŏ Confucian ideologues were either mistaken in their confidence in certain institutions that 
they thought constituted essential elements of a Confucian state (like the examination system, which had been criticized by Chu Hsi 
and a number of other Neo-Confucian worthies), or they neglected to rectify things that they mistakenly thought were legitimate and 
acceptable (like inherited slavery). 
 
The Period of Degeneration 
 
Chapter 2 will be devoted to a discussion of the forms of degeneration and change in early Chosŏn institutions that brought both the 
Chosŏn dynasty and the Korean nation to the verge of destruction in the 1590s. These forms can be conveniently divided into 
conventional categories. In politics, the Confucian emphasis on limited monarchy, equal opportunity for all men of moral rectitude to 
move into the ranks of officialdom, and probity in administrative behavior was undermined by regal aspirations to tyranny, the raw 
political ambition of officials, favoritism, factional coalition in defense of personal interest, and backbiting calumny against political 
rivals. In society, reciprocity based on an exchange of loyalty and noblesse oblige and the bestowal of honor and prestige in accordance 
with moral capacity was overwhelmed by the narrower and more traditional bonds of blood and kinship that were carried over from the 
hoary traditions of the Silla and Koryŏ dynasties. An ever-narrowing group of yangban semiaristocrats closed off all access to their ranks 
by the use of inherited wealth and privilege and sharp-eyed selection of marriage partners, and an ever-increasing body of slaves were 
prevented by the stigma of birth from receiving the dignity due to ordinary human beings. This was possibly the most egregious 
anomaly in Confucian society, an hereditary aristocracy of blood and kin in the midst of a slave society (approximately 30 percent of the 
population) that beggared the promise of the Confucian message that only the most worthy men would lead, and only the least worthy 
would hold up the rear and bear the burden of support. 
In military defense, an optimum system of service for all, given the conventional exemptions of yangban and slaves, a state of 
readiness blessed by a nationwide system of garrisons, and a high state of morale and an uncorrupted officer corps were all weakened 
and virtually destroyed. There had been an expansion of exemptions, replacement of duty soldiers by tax payments, a disappearance of 
troops from garrisons, and neglect by officers of the conditions of their garrisons and the training of their men in order to profit from 
support payments from the taxpayers. In civil administration, a body of reasonably honest officials and clerks and a modicum of 
cooperation at the village level between local officials and their clerks, the local elders and ordinary peasants had been lost. The clerks, 
who were shorn of their salaries by the new dynasty, began to scramble for fees and gratuities to support themselves, to accept bribes 
from men seeking favors, to peddle their influence, and to funnel illicit gains to their superiors in the regular bureaucracy. Cooperation 
disappeared as the local gentry lost their public spirit in their attempts to evade taxes and service, and reinforced their superiority as 
landlords and creditors at the expense of the peasantry. The communality and commonality of village life was undermined by divisions 
of status, wealth, and class. 
In economic distribution, a reasonable system of distribution based on the secure possession of plots of land for every peasant 
family was lost as the ranks of the dispossessed increased, as smallholders became tenants or hired laborers of rich landlords, or as the 
truly distressed commended themselves to others as slaves. In taxation, a logical, tripartite system of taxes geared to a predominantly 
agrarian and noncommercial society in which a grain tax on land, a labor service tax on labor, and the collection in kind of special 
tribute products from villages was kept to the lowest possible level to guarantee subsistence to the peasant was left far behind. The 
tribute system was gradually replaced by private contracting arrangements and illicit market transactions, service was skewed by marked 
and conspicuous evasion with heavier transfers to those still in the system, and the grain tax remained too small to cover official 
disbursements. 
In commerce and industry, a regulated system to restrict commerce and industry to the supply of necessary goods for the ruling 
class in the capital and bare necessities for subsistence peasants in the countryside was undermined. Private merchants had begun to 
break free from restrictions, engage in both wholesale and retail trade, accumulate capital, and to corner markets to make larger profits, 
and private artisans began to abscond from their state employers to produce goods for the market on their own. 
What was the nature of this transition? It certainly represented the degeneration of the institutions created at the beginning of the 
dynasty, but not all such developments were negative because departures from a restricted and controlled economy could be regarded 
by many as favorable and progressive developments of a freer economy. Can we pin labels on it redolent of the transition from tradition 
to modernity, like the journey from feudalism to capitalism, from communal land to private property, from bound labor to free labor, 
from licensed monopolies or guilds to free merchants and free markets, from stagnation to development? There are certainly 
resemblances between these changes in Korea from the late fifteenth through the early seventeenth centuries that appear similar to 
those in the West from the eleventh through fifteenth centuries, but bedrock differences remained, impervious to facile comparison. 
Land was privately owned from the outset, but it lacked an independent legal system to guarantee it against predators, whether the state 
or influential private parties. The economic and political systems were not feudal in the classical Western sense because the centralized 
bureaucratic state was already in place, autonomous fiefs were not granted to military vassals, and the peasants were not bound to the 
land. About one-third of the labor supply was unfree, and they were chattel slaves, closer perhaps to the social system of ancient Rome 
than either the Western Middle Ages or early modern Europe. The smallholders, tenants, and hired laborers were legally free, but still 
repressed by state officials, landlords, and local magnates – and they remained that way to the end of the dynasty. The economic system 
did experience a loosening of the bonds and regulations imposed at the beginning of the dynasty, but the growth of the market and 
private merchant activity was restricted, licensed monopolies remained to the end of the dynasty alongside unlicensed or private 
merchants, and currency, either in metallic or paper form, disappeared entirely from the market just as other, presumably “progressive” 
developments in the economy were taking place. 
Finally, class structure was not moving in the direction of freedom. Mobility there was, both upward and downward, but because the 
yangban class at the top through the highest civil service examination (munkwa) was becoming narrower, and the class of hereditary 
slaves were remaining in place if not growing in size until about 1780–1800, there was no corollary liberalization of society to 
accompany moderate economic liberalization. The state, not terribly powerful but stronger than it had been in any past dynasty, 
remained under the control of a class of bureaucrats educated in Neo-Confucian thought but recruited primarily from the ranks of the 
yangban families, not the general public. 
 
The Disaster of the Imjin War, 1592–98 
 
Could the Chosŏn dynasty, the political entity that prevailed over this disintegrating system, have continued indefinitely? If Chinese 
history were to provide the template for comparison, it would have been unlikely. There were too many things wrong in 1592 for Korean 
society to have continued much longer without popular rebellion. In any case, we will never know, because a deus ex machina in the 
form of the Hideyoshi war machine with a century of practice in bloody combat and armed with its new Portuguese-style muskets and 
cannon cut a bloody swath through the Korean countryside. If anyone had had any doubts about the health of the Chosŏn dynasty, its 
utter incapacity for self-defense removed those doubts forever. 
Prior to the invasions only a few men of foresight could see trouble brewing from the weakness of domestic institutions and the 
growing threat from Japan, but most of the public was complacent. Once the invasion hit the country, however, everyone was aware that 
Chosŏn institutions were at fault, and that something had to be done to prevent a recurrence of disaster in the future. 
What might have been called to task to atone for the disaster were some of the fundamentals of governance: the monarchy, 
inherited privilege and slavery, and Confucian ideology. King Sŏnjo could easily have been held responsible for failing to foresee the 
Japanese threat and strengthen defenses. Inherited privilege could have been identified as the reason for the incompetence of the 
bureaucracy and for the evasion of tax and service by the yangban. Confucianism might have been held responsible for its inability to 
stem the deficiency of morale, the loss of bureaucratic honesty and devotion, the loss of revenues and service, and the inefficiency of 
government. But because the invasion was sudden and descended on the people like a natural disaster, neither king nor monarchy, 
neither inherited privilege nor slavery, and neither Confucian philosophy nor Confucian statecraft were held responsible. 
Leszek Kolakowski, in attempting to explain why the Communist system in Russia and East Europe did not collapse long before 
1989, remarked that supposedly objective measures of decrepitude like economic inefficiency and wartime disaster were not sufficient 
to overthrow a regime without the mental readiness of the population for it. “As with most closed ideological systems, communism was 
for a long time immune to criticism, and no empirical evidence to the contrary made a difference, since the ideology could easily absorb 
any facts that seemed to falsify it and dismiss them as irrelevant.” The same statement could be applied to Korean faith in Confucian 
ethics and statecraft in the seventeenth century. What chance could there have been for the overthrow of Confucianism and the 
institutions of bureaucratic monarchy when there was no observable challenge to its monopoly over the Korean mind at the time? There 
was no equivalent to the “slow but inexorable erosion of Communism as a living faith” in Chosŏn Korea in that period.¹⁵ 
 
Seventeenth-Century Reconstruction 
 
Since the evidence of failure did not provoke an attack on the ideological beliefs and institutional arrangements that produced it, the 
survivors of the Imjin War set about searching for ways to remedy the major problems without a revolutionary abandonment of these 
impedimenta. Yu Hyŏngwŏn was also captive to this general mood, for he spent most of his adult lifetime in a search through the 
materials of his beloved tradition for solutions to institutional breakdown. He was convinced that it was not the Confucian tradition that 
was at fault for Korea’s problems, but the misguided way that it had been applied. 
In the half century before Yu Hyŏngwŏn took up his pen, change began to appear in Chosŏn institutions, some initiated by 
reformist officials, others as manifestations of trends beneath the surface but under way for over a century. Some of these changes were 
failures. After 1598 political power was determined more than ever by factions, culminating in the successful coup against King 
Kwanghaegun in 1623. In the rebuilding of the military defense system, the shortage of troops was overcome, not by the enlistment of 
the yangban malingerers and draft dodgers, but by the incorporation of slaves into the military for the first time. 
The restructuring of military defense was adversely affected by the influence of factional politics. The new divisions created after 
1623 became playthings of the politicians who participated in the coup of that time, and the consequence was the weakening of national 
defense and eventually defeats in 1627 and 1637 at the hands of the Manchus, who in 1644 succeeded in overturning the Ming empire. 
After the Manchu victory in 1637, the Manchus chose not to rule directly but imposed harsh terms of tribute on the Korean economy 
and kept a sharp eye on the Korean military system to ensure that no major rearmament projects that might lead to an alliance with the 
surviving Ming restorationist armies could be pursued. 
A respite was provided in the rebuilding of the economy because the destruction of land and the loss of population created a 
surplus of land and allowed the survivors to begin to restore their fields to annual production, but the state chose not to interfere in the 
system of distribution. It chose to reduce the land tax to a minimum for the benefit of reconstruction, but it allowed the return of 
yangban and landlords to their lands, the mobilization of private resources and capital, and the continuation of slavery and tenancy for 
the cultivation of large holdings. 
The most striking changes took place in the economy. In the agrarian sector new techniques and methods spread and served to 
increase production, allowing surpluses that gradually began to be marketed. The state sought to convert tribute contracting into a 
system of state purchase of necessities from merchants and the market, which stimulated commerce. Officials sought to introduce 
metallic currency into the market to increase the speed and efficiency of exchange, and private merchants began to expand their 
activities beyond the restrictions of licensed merchants. 
Thus, when Yu Hyŏngwŏn began to write his massive study of the problems of contemporary statecraft, Korean conditions had 
changed significantly from the previous century, but the Chosŏn government had by no means solved its major problems in the fifty 
years since the Imjin War. Yu had to decide whether the bureaucratic monarchy was functioning the way it should, whether the king had 
too much or too little power, and whether the right men were being recruited into government positions. He faced problems of agrarian 
reconstruction, land distribution, taxation, and military service. He had to decide whether the current system of landownership based 
on inheritance, purchase, and sale, and the use of slaves and tenants for the cultivation of estates should be maintained or changed. He 
had to ponder the problems caused by a largely hereditary and privileged yangban ruling class and a slave society. He had to 
contemplate the methods for the recreation of national defense in the face of Manchu surveillance. He had to decide whether the 
economic changes stemming from the taedong reform of the tribute system, the expansion of market and commercial activity, and the 
introduction of currency into the economy should be checked in favor of a return to the simpler economy of early Chosŏn times, or 
accepted and promoted. In general, he had to decide whether to maintain fundamental principles or adjust to changing circumstances 
and, devotée of Confucian statecraft wisdom as he was, he had to find a way to apply that lore to the problems of his age. 
 
FORMAT OF THE BOOK: PARTS II–VI 
 
This book will be divided into five sections (Parts II–VI) to deal with the major topics that Yu discussed in his Pan’gye surok. In each 
case, the presentation of Yu’s ideas will be fit into the context of the previous history of the institutions involved and the development 
of those institutions after his death to illustrate the source of the influences on him, and the influence of his ideas on subsequent 
policies. 
The first three parts of the book will be related to the central question of inherited status, particularly the yangban ruling class and 
the slaves. Part II on Social Reform will explore Yu’s solution to two questions: what he regarded as a thoroughly inappropriate manner 
for the education and recruitment of officials that had resulted in the domination of officeholding by a closed group of yangban, and the 
suffering and injustice visited on a third of the population and the loss of their services to the state by the system of hereditary slavery. 
Part III on Land Reform will discuss Yu’s conclusion that the main cause for the maldistribution of wealth was the concentration of 
private landed property in the hands of the yangban and landlords, and his proposals for eliminating this system and achieving an 
equitable redistribution of land. It will also discuss the subsequent history of land reform thought and policy to the early nineteenth 
century to determine whether Yu’s ideas had any influence on policy, and whether they set in motion a progressive movement leading to 
more radical or modern solutions. 
Since the allocation of service was also related to the weakness of national defense stemming from exemptions and nonregistration 
of yangban and slaves on the basis of inherited status and other privileges, the material in Part IV on Military Reform will discuss Yu’s 
methods for solving this problem. Part IV will also deal with national defense in general, including strategy, tactics, weapons, and 
fortifications, in order to judge the flexibility and receptivity to new developments, but the section will end with coverage of 
developments in military organization and service from Yu’s death to the end of the nineteenth century. In that period the Ch’ing peace 
eliminated any foreign military threat and shifted Korean attention to the financial problems relating to the support of the military. As 
military defense shifted away from strategy, tactics, and weapons to finance, the distribution of service and taxation once again returned 
to the center of attention. This meant that the inequity in the distribution of that burden based on exemptions and evasion became a 
serious problem that affected the lives of the mass of the population and the very viability of the dynasty. In that context, Yu’s ideas 
were an important part of the debate over reform. 
Part V will shift focus to the consideration of Yu’s plan for the reform of the central bureaucracy and its mode of operation, and Part 
VI will treat the economic changes that were taking place in the seventeenth century, Yu’s response to them, and developments that 
occurred through the end of the eighteenth century. The chapters in Part V will deal with agencies involved with the king and his court, 
the central and local government, including both regular officials and clerks, and the attempt to reinvigorate institutions of local 




=====
EPILOGUE 
The Complexities of Korean Confucian Statecraft 
 
This book has been devoted to a study of Confucian statecraft in the last half of the Chosŏn dynasty with respect not only to its ideas, 
but to its relevance to government policy and action. The material presented in the text reveals that it is very difficult, if not impossible, 
to define Confucian statecraft in action in simple terms for a number of reasons. The ideas that constituted the Confucian statecraft 
tradition were not always internally consistent. The conflict between historical contingency and ideal Confucian objectives inhibited or 
obstructed the achievement of those objectives; antinomies within Confucian thought and practice guaranteed conflict over the 
definition of goals and priorities; and the impossibility of recovering the ideal norms of classical antiquity because of the irreversibility 
of the transition from the Chou feudalism to Ch’in centralized bureaucracy meant that difference of opinion was unavoidable over the 
crucial question of compromise between the ideal and the real. For these reasons, the statecraft thought of Yu Hyŏngwŏn, which has 
constituted the focus of this study, cannot be taken as the only, the best, or the most representative example of Korean Confucian 
statecraft thought in Korea. Some of his ideas were truly unusual and some were acceptable to most Confucians, but others were 
rejected as unworkable, even by those who regarded themselves as his intellectual disciples. The reason why I chose him as the focus 
for this study was because he was the first Korean scholar of the Chosŏn dynasty to write a thorough and comprehensive analysis of the 
deficiencies of his society in the seventeenth century, providing us with an excellent entrée into statecraft writing and the nature and 
complexity of a Korean Confucian society under stress. His scheme for the rectification of institutions provides a template for us to 
compare the ideas and policies of both scholars and officials involved in the contemplation of policy to the end of the dynasty. 
 
THE INCOMPLETENESS OF THE CONFUCIAN TRANSFORMATION 
 
At the beginning of the Chosŏn dynasty, there were very few people in Korean society who would be regarded as thoroughgoing 
Confucians because despite the presence of Confucian ideas for two millennia, Buddhism functioned as the dominant religion at the 
upper levels of society, and folk religion, which included animistic spirit worship and shamanism, was pervasive among the rural 
peasantry. The new dynasty was ushered in by a small coterie of converts to the Neo-Confucian doctrines of Sung dynasty China, 
particularly as digested and recapitulated by Chu Hsi in the twelfth century. These men set out on an effort to convert all of Korea to 
belief in Neo-Confucian principles and the practice of Confucian norms. 
They and their successors at the top of government and society went a long way to achieving their aims, but they never fully 
completed their task. Even though the peasants were eventually converted to Confucian ancestor worship and patrilineal family 
organization and the like, they never fully discarded their fear of the spirits in general. Total conversion of Korean society to Confucian 
belief was also hindered because its educational enterprise was underfunded. The early Chosŏn state’s official school system proved a 
failure even before the end of the fifteenth century, and even the private academies after the mid-sixteenth century were not created to 
educate all benighted peasants. Their Confucian overlords needed them more in the fields than in the schoolroom. 
The inadequacy of mass education was not the only reason for the violation of Confucian norms and standards in real life. Many of 
the officials who had been schooled and indoctrinated in Confucian moral standards placed private interest over the public good, took 
bribes to enrich themselves and their own families, exploited peasants and slaves to increase their wealth, and foreclosed on mortgages 
to expand their landed properties instead of fulfilling their role as moral examplars for society at large. Even though Neo-Confucian 
bureaucrats were supposed to run Korean affairs as they would a moral order, many of them were incapable of living up to the high 
standards of the moral code. 
In this sense the history of the Chosŏn dynasty could be viewed as a morality play in which a solid core of true believers did battle 
with the reality of human weakness and foible. Neo-Confucians understood the persistence of human imperfection because they had 
been taught that inner goodness in the mind was obscured or obstructed by psychophysical force. Historical experience had also 
demonstrated that dynasties were not static or perpetual; they had a life of their own that led to decline marked by the breakdown of 
social order and rebellion in which the forces of evil seemed to win the day. 
Confucianism, however, was not discredited despite its failure to halt moral and dynastic decline because of the view that chaos and 
disorder was the fault of leadership, education, or institutions, not the moral philosophy itself. Confucian standards could outlive one 
dynasty and be resuscitated by the next. Confucian thought was thus preserved as the dominant system of belief and the source of 
statecraft wisdom from the Sung through Ch’ing dynasties in China despite the overthrow of individual dynasties. Korea had only one 
dynasty dominated by the Confucian vision, the Chosŏn dynasty. It should have come to an end in 1592 when Hideyoshi invaded Korea 
because by that time the Chosŏn state had been weakened by maladministration, internecine bureaucratic factionalism, unfair taxation, 
the concentration of wealth, the evasion of responsibility, and the deterioration of national defense. If Confucian statecraft were to be 
judged by consideration of the results of a government run by Confucians, Confucian statecraft should have been deemed a failure in 
1592. But when the war was over in 1598 both the Chosŏn state and the Confucian philosophy that guided it remained intact. 
 
Confucianism in the Midst of Contingent Circumstance 
 
When Neo-Confucianism was adopted as the leading belief and ideology at the beginning of the Chosŏn dynasty, society and social 
institutions were already well developed. The state was organized as a monarchical bureaucracy, and society was structured 
hierarchically on the basis of hereditary or semihereditary principles, including strict discrimination between status categories. This 
situation alone meant that the early Chosŏn Neo-Confucians had inherited institutions that were less than ideal. 
Monarchy and Centralized Bureaucracy. The existence of a ruler or monarch had been recognized by Confucians as a necessity for 
civilized government since Confucius himself, but absolute monarchy and a centralized government organization had always been 
major problems for Confucian statecraft thinkers. Rulers could be a danger and threat to the Confucian moral and social order because 
they were usually more concerned with the retention of their political power than conformity to moral norms. Confucians had an 
ambiguous if not contradictory attitude toward rulers, particularly the bad ones. Mencius had taught that since an immoral ruler lost his 
Heavenly Mandate to rule, the population had the right to overthrow him and replace him with another. Confucians might justifiably 
withdraw their loyalty from such an immoral ruler, but they might also feel that it was their duty to stick with him to lead him from 
immorality to morality. 
Because Confucian thought emphasized loyalty to the ruler, some have believed that Confucian thought was conducive to the 
creation of monarchical despotism, especially in the Ming and Ch’ing dynasties in China. The Korean situation was somewhat different 
because most Confucian officials were drawn from yangban families with a long history of honor, wealth, prestige, and status that 
outshone the royal clan. It is true that at the beginning of the dynasty they supported an army general in his usurpation of the throne 
because they felt that greater royal authority was essential for transforming society from Buddhism and animism to Confucian belief. 
But once the new dynasty was in place, the Confucian officials began what became a protracted battle against most kings to preserve 
their own families’ hold on power, wealth, and position, and to induce them to accept Confucian standards of statecraft. 
When the Chosŏn dynasty appeared, Korea had long been organized as a centralized bureaucracy, but centralization had been 
incomplete, at least by the standards of most Chinese dynasties. The Neo-Confucian supporters of the new dynasty successfully 
overcame that deficiency by extending central control to all the districts of the kingdom, but they were never enamored of centralized 
bureaucracy as the best form of government organization because it represented the political system of the Ch’in dynasty that had 
destroyed the beloved feudal political configuration of the Chou dynasty in the late third century B.C. 
The Ch’in bureaucratic system was based on Legalist thought that seemed diametrically opposed to Confucian moral philosophy. 
The Legalists took a negative view of human nature, eschewed moral education and persuasion as useless methods for the 
establishment of order, and insisted on the necessity of reward and punishment as the only means for keeping human beings under 
control. All Confucian officials who served bureaucratic dynasties after the Ch’in had to use punishment as the means for enforcing 
conformity. Some sought to temper it with Confucian compassion, but others became such adept users of coercion that punishment 
became as much a feature of the bureaucratic Confucian state as moral suasion. Even the most moralistic Neo-Confucians resorted to 
punishment as the ultimate recourse for forcing the ignorant and recalcitrant to conform to Confucian moral ideals, revealed only so 
clearly in Yu Hyŏngwŏn’s regulations for the conduct of his proposed schools. Yet most Confucians believed that the unmitigated use 
of punishment was symptomatic of the moral failure of the ruler and the state. 
Unfortunately centralized bureaucracy had proved to be permanent, and Confucians had to adjust to these unfortunate 
circumstances as the only way for their philosophy to survive. The conflict between the two ideals – moral suasion versus coercion – 
was never solved, and the dividing line between the two was left to arbitrary judgment or circumstance. 
The Social Legacy: Heredity, Property, and Slavery. The ruling class of the early Chosŏn dynasty consisted of yangban families that 
constituted a semiaristocratic bureaucratic elite that owed much of their prominence to the inheritance of status, and they ruled over a 
slave society sustained by the system of inherited slave status. Neo-Confucians in the first two centuries of the dynasty barely raised the 
question of the moral conflict between Confucian principles and semihereditary bureaucracy and hereditary slavery. It was not until the 
immense pressure exerted on the Chosŏn state by a series of catastrophic invasions after 1592 that the Confucian bureaucrats began to 
think of requiring idle yangban and slaves to perform military service. 
The inheritance of social status, whether yangban or slave, was not only responsible for revenue shortages and inadequate defense 
because of tax-exemption privileges, it also contributed significantly to obstructing the achievement of the Confucian ideal of expanded 
opportunity for education and officeholding. The preservation of class interest by yangban landlords and slaveowners was the main 
obstacle to converting society to a moral basis for the distribution of prestige, office, and wealth, but reform was made doubly difficult 
by the antinomies within the Confucian moral system. Confucians were morally obliged to preserve the patrimony of their families, 
including slaves as well as real estate, and to show the utmost respect for one’s elders and superiors in the social order, a moral 
obligation used by landlords and slaveowners to legitimize private property and slavery. 
Even though the idealistic Confucians agreed that the virtuous ruler was obliged to guarantee subsistence to the common peasant, 
ideally through the grant of a minimal plot of arable land according to the well-field model of the Chou dynasty, they were faced with the 
reality of private property that had determined land tenure in Korea for over a millennium. Since the early Chosŏn kings ignored appeals 
for nationalization and egalitarian redistribution, they confirmed the private property of the landlords and opened the door to the 
recreation of the same conditions in the maldistribution of wealth that had prevailed in the late fourteenth century. As a result most 
Confucians paid only lip service to the notion of national ownership and egalitarian redistribution. 
Even less attention was paid to hereditary slavery that had been in practice since the tenth or eleventh centuries, possibly because 
slavery itself had never been condemned as immoral. At least the question of hereditary enslavement of the innocent should have been 
raised by committed Confucians, but few did so. In any case, the class interests of the landlords and slaveowners in a slave society 
constituted an insuperable obstacle to idealistic Confucian purists. 
 
Agriculture over Commerce and Industry 
 
These class interests were abetted by the overpowering and enduring belief by Confucian scholars and officials alike that agricultural 
production was the only legitimate way to produce wealth. Food and clothing were necessary to subsistence, but all else was 
superfluous and contributed to unnecessary, ostentatious, and immoral consumption. Industry and commerce were acknowledged as 
necessary activities, but only in a limited way. Artisans had a role to play in providing the population with necessary nonagricultural 
goods, but any expansion in the production of luxury items would corrupt the morals of the people. Likewise commerce was necessary 
for the circulation of goods, but any excessive profiteering would reduce the production of necessities by inducing peasants to abandon 
their primary agricultural tasks in pursuit of commercial profit. 
These ideal principles were compromised in real life because the nobility, yangban, landlords, and the rich were allowed to enjoy the 
luxuries of life, the skilled artisans were employed, often by the state, in producing the brocades, silks, fine pottery, and other 
“unnecessary” items of conspicuous consumption, and merchants were subsidized, often with monopoly licenses, to provide those 
items to the king and upper class. Only the peasants were left to fulfill the Confucian moral norms of frugality, but more by deprivation 
and the lack of wealth than by adherence to abstract moral norms. These violations of Confucian norms of simplicity, frugality, and 
modesty existed in every dynasty because those with the wealth to buy luxury goods refused to dispense with them. Confucians had 
either to engage in constant scolding of the recalcitrant or resign themselves to tacit or hypocritical acceptance of human weakness. The 
Physiocratic emphasis on agricultural production and the concomitant denigration of industrial and commercial activity in Korean 
Confucian thought supported the preeminent economic and political position of the landlords by hindering the accumulation of wealth 
by artisans and merchants, and by forbidding their participation in the competition for bureaucratic office. 
International trade did not provide a major stimulus to commerce in general because of the restrictions of the tributary system with 
China, the suspicion and lack of trust between Koreans and their Chinese or Manchu suzerains, the predatory aggressions of the Wakō 
pirates from Japan in the fifteenth century, the involvement of the Japanese with their own internal wars in the sixteenth century, and the 
reimposition of severe limits on foreign trade activity after the Shimabara Rebellion of 1636. In fact, these real limits on international 
trade probably accounted as much as Confucian doctrine for the restrictions on the development of the economy. 
 
Bureaucratic Routinization and Crisis 
 
Chinese had experienced the rise and fall of dynasties so frequently in their long history that they became convinced that dynasties had 
a life of their own governed as much by bureaucratic routinization and laxity as the loss of moral fiber. Korean dynasties lasted for much 
longer periods than the Chinese for a number of complex reasons, but the Chosŏn dynasty began to exhibit characteristics of 
bureaucratic deterioriation by the end of the fifteenth century. 
Laxity and corruption in administration that increased over time meant that registration of the taxpaying population was not 
maintained, taxes and services were levied more heavily on the poorest peasants, and military service was eroded by evasion. 
Bureaucratic laxity and corruption was exacerbated by the elimination of salaries for all clerks at the beginning of the dynasty. The 
policy was undertaken by the regular officials to elevate themselves over the influential local hyangni or local clerk class of the late Koryŏ 
and prevent them from rising to the regular bureaucracy, but it forced all clerks into a life of corruption by demanding fees and 
gratuities to make a living. 
By the end of the sixteenth century the capacity of the bureaucracy to rectify the problems of maladministration was weakened by the 
emergence of internecine factional strife within the bureaucracy after 1575. The unfortunate consequence of this sad state of affairs was 
the devastation wrought by Hideyoshi’s invasions in the 1590s. Someone looking at Korea in 1598 after the last of the Japanese returned 
home, might well have concluded that both the Chosŏn dynasty and the experiment in Confucian statecraft had been a failure. 
 
THE SEVENTEETH-CENTURY GOVERNMENT REFORM PROGRAM 
 
Even before the Japanese invasions a number of Confucian bureaucrats had sounded the clarion call of reform. Yulgok (Yi I), by his 
analysis of the failure of domestic institutions and the weakness of the military, and Cho Hŏn, by his comparison of Chosŏn 
deficiencies with Ming advantages in administration, commerce, and other areas, led the appeal for institutional rectification, but their 
appeals were largely ignored. 
Ironically the devastation of the Imjin Wars solved some of the major problems of the dynasty and gave Confucian statecraft a 
second chance. While the destruction of land and property reduced both individual wealth as well as state revenue, it alleviated 
population pressure on the land, induced a period of tax remission, and allowed peasants a period to revive agricultural production. 
Even though the government had a lower tax base, it was able to begin land and population registration again as a basis for future 
revenues and service. The irregularity of the local product tribute tax and the injustice of its operation in practice led to conversion of 
the system. Intimate contact with Ming officials made Korean officials more aware of the far greater development of commerce and 
economic activity in China than Korea, and stimulated the emulation of some Ming commercial practices. In short, national catastrophe 
laid the basis for a reform effort in the seventeenth century that was by no means totally successful, but resulted in important 
institutional reforms. 
Defeat in battle awakened the regime to the problem of tax and service evasion and stimulated measures to broaden requirements 
by bringing idle yangban, tax evaders, and slaves into the military service system. It stimulated the establishment of new divisions and 
the adoption of Western firearms. The leading role in this reform effort was played by active officials rather than armchair scholars. 
Of course, the record of accomplishment in this century was mixed. The most obvious failure in the reform effort was the attempt to 
reconstitute a viable military force. The formation of new divisions was influenced more by political considerations than by the logic of 
national defense, and the Yi Kwal rebellion of 1624 shifted priorities from national defense to the prevention of rebellion. 
A second factor was the inability of the regime to recruit and retrain a sufficient force of foot soldiers, and to recognize the 
importance of firearms and training in their use. The government must have relaxed its efforts after conclusion of a treaty with the 
Japanese in 1609 and underestimated the military strength of the Manchus. 
Probably the most important reason for the disasters of the two Manchu invasions of 1627 and 1637, however, was the change in 
foreign policy from Kwanghaegun’s regime, a change that has to be attributed to Confucian influence. It was, after all, the Westerner 
faction that seized power in a coup d’état in 1623 and insisted on outright support for the Ming dynasty because of its moral obligation 
to the Ming Wan-li emperor for his (belated) dispatch of reinforcements to Korea in 1592. The Westerners were intellectually and 
morally incapable of continuing Kwanghaegun’s more pragmatic policy of adaptation and delay. What was worse, after the Manchu 
imposition of sovereignty over Korea, it became impossible for Korean kings to rebuild Korean military forces in the face of Manchu 
surveillance. 
Under the protection of the Manchu Ch’ing dynasty, however, the threat of foreign invasion was removed and a strong military 
defense became unnecessary. The armed forces were kept in place mainly to ensure domestic tranquillity, but because its cost was far 
too large for that purpose, it functioned more and more as an oppressive mode of taxation. Since military service was deemed 
demeaning to begin with, the tendency to evade it grew, and a smaller and smaller group of commoner peasants were left to carry the 
whole fiscal burden. The most serious weakness of the Ch’ing peace, however, was the desuetude with which officials considered 
military defense because when the Ch’ing state lost its power in the nineteenth century to defend itself, let alone its Korean tributary, 
Korea found itself helpless and isolated. 
The need for more adult males for the payment of the military support tax, if not actual duty as soldiers, continued to stimulate 
plans for drawing more slaves into the military service system or liberating them from inherited slavery. During the Imjin Wars slaves 
were incorporated in considerable numbers into the sog’o units and manumitted in return for military merit or purchase, but after the 
war the price of purchase was too high to allow much reduction of the slave population. The need for adult males subject to military 
service, however, kept slaves as military support taxpayers. The same motive also explains the origin in official circles of the long debate 
over the matrilineal rule for the manumission of offspring of the sons of commoner mothers in mixed slave/commoner marriages, first 
instituted in 1669. This marked an important step in the state’s interference with the slaveowner’s control over his slaves. 
The idea for reforming the local products tribute system began in the late fifteenth century, but the stimulus needed to accomplish 
the task also occurred as a result of the Imjin Wars. The illicit system of tribute contracting underway since the late fifteenth century 
demonstrated the advantages of market purchases of goods over in-kind tax payments, and state officials simply applied to the whole 
country what had already been tried by some officials – financing the cost by an extra tax. The taedong reform carried out in the 
seventeenth century contributed to even greater commercial activity than before. 
Almost the same officials who championed the adoption of the taedong reform also pioneered the introduction of metallic currency. 
From their observation of the Ming economy they realized that metallic currency was needed to overcome the cumbersome use of grain 
and cloth as media of exchange to lubricate market transactions. 
The reform of the military system, the matrilineal rule in mixed marriages, the taedong law, and the currency reform of the 
seventeenth century represented a series of positive responses to serious problems by active Confucian officials, and their policies 
provided both inspiration and working models for the new statecraft scholars. 
 
YU HYŎNGWŎN’S REFORM PLANS 
 
The response to crisis is certainly one of the main reasons why Korean scholars in the seventeenth century began to shift their attention 
from Confucian moral metaphysics to the problems of statecraft. The same thing happened in the late Ming dynasty and spawned the 
statecraft writings of Ku Yen-wu and Huang Tsung-hsi, but Yu Hyŏngwŏn, unaware of their existence, derived no inspiration from them. 
In China the reaction against Sung learning in the sixteenth-century Ming period took the form of Wang Yang-ming’s emphasis on 
the inner, meditational approach to self-rectification rather than the apparently external and superficial approach to book learning and 
scripture by Chu Hsi and Sung Learning. Since Wang Yang-ming had been condemned as a heretic by T’oegye (Yi Hwang) in Korea in 
the mid-sixteenth century, very few Koreans became followers of his thought. Born into the Northerner faction, Yu must have abided by 
T’oegye’s condemnation to adhere to the teachings of Chu Hsi and the Sung school, but he insisted that the study of institutions as 
well as book learning was critical to the rectification of self and society. 
Using better institutions to find moral men to assume office was only part of his plan. He also believed that there was only one 
model for perfect institutions – the systems used by the sages in ancient China, but because he agreed that a literal recreation of ancient 
institutions was unworkable, he did his best to extract principles that would work in quite different circumstances under the mode of 
centralized bureaucracy. 
The degree to which he departed from ancient institutions and compromised with current reality varied from one institution to 
another. In some cases, he appeared tainted by blind fundamentalism, despite his demurral to the contrary, when he insisted that the 
carving out of embossed squares in the landscape would remedy the administrative problems caused by population growth, 
geographical mobility, and laxity in registration. In others, he modified ancient institutions by compromising with post-Chou reality 
whether of the Chinese or Korean variety. 
For example, he was most adamant in demanding a program of nationalization and redistribution of land to eliminate the evil of 
private property, and yet he rejected the idea that he was simply copying the well-field system of ancient Chou China. Since he felt that it 
was as necessary to create a hierarchy of wealth that would match the moral capacity of his new officials rather than the inherited 
prestige of the yangban or their talent in literary composition, he prescribed extra allotments to those officials – a plan that he compared 
to the limited-field system of the Han dynasty. In short, he claimed he was fusing Chou and Han models as the optimum 
accommodation to post-Chou circumstance. Furthermore, he supported his argument for the 100 myo basic land allotment by a 
practical proof, rather than just a blind appeal to the classics, by demonstrating that there was sufficient land area in Korea to provide 
for the the Korean population. 
Although Yu argued that he selected crucial elements of ancient patterns on reasonable and empirical grounds, many of his choices 
were really arbitrary and idiosyncratic. Other Confucians could and did ignore his insistence on the embossed square and the 
superiority of the 100-myo unit, for example, let alone the need for confiscation and nationalization of private property. 
In his rejection of hereditary slavery, he argued that slavery was unjustified because all human beings were essentially the same and 
none deserved to be treated as chattel, but by no means did he really signify an absolute commitment to equality or a justification on 
rational grounds alone. To the contrary, he sought ultimate authority in classical precedent, which prescribed slavery as an appropriate 
punishment for certain serious crimes, but never as a status to be inherited by innocent children. True to this principle he never called 
for the total manumission of all slaves, just an end to inherited slavery. On the other hand, he clearly communicated his willingness to 
compromise with Korean tradition by tolerating the continuation of slavery for a period far longer than one generation. He provided for 
them to continue to work for their masters, receive a land grant from the state, continue their participation as soldiers and support 
taxpayers, serve as clerks and runners in official agencies, and assume inferior roles in his regulations for his community compacts. His 
support for adoption of the matrilineal rule also reflected his acknowledgment that the reduction of slaves in society would take several 
generations. 
He extolled the virtues of the Chou system of militia service, but his plan for the reform of military service was only indirectly related 
to the militia ideal. Instead, he urged a return to the early Chosŏn system of discrete rotating duty soldiers supported by a separate body 
of support taxpayers, but he justified its relation to the militia system by arguing that it was a self-sufficient method of finance that did 
not drain revenues from the state exchequer. Assigning support taxpayers to duty soldiers was far better than loading a heavy tax burden 
on the population for financing the burdensome professional soldiers created by expansionist dynasties in the post-Chou era. Here 
again, he demonstrated flexibility in one dimension countered by dogmatic rigidity in another. After all, a professional military corps 
might have been just what Korea needed in view of the sorry performance of regular Chosŏn troops against the Japanese and Manchus. 
His respect for early Chosŏn military organization was not matched, however, by his rejection of the tribute system, which he 
condemned in practice even though it had been created by the venerated founders of the Chosŏn dynasty. He was convinced of the 
logical and empirical superiority of an increased land tax as a method for financing both material purchases and other administrative 
costs of both the king and the state, but he was not content to rely on logic alone. He defended his position on the grounds that tribute, 
particularly royal tribute, was an immoral and unrestrained exercise in monarchical acquisitiveness that deserved to be brought under 
control by a more reasonable system of taxation. 
His admiration for hired or wage labor as a means of replacing slave cultivators on the estates of the large landlords or 
uncompensated labor service by commoners certainly appeared as a rational and innovative response to changing circumstances rather 
than a dogmatic mimicking of classical precedent. He argued that wage or hired labor was preferable to slave labor on moral grounds 
because it would eliminate the cruel and coercive treatment of slaves, and on apparently liberal grounds because hired laborers entered 
into employment by free choice and willing agreement. 
These arguments undeniably had aspects of humaneness and liberalism to them, but his thinking was by no means free of the 
constraints relevant to his times. He did not argue that wage labor had proved its superiority by his own observation of contemporary 
facts, but rather by hearsay information about wage labor in China. Wage labor was not a new phenomenon; it had been around since 
long before the beginning of the dynasty without doing damage to Korean social custom. In fact, he argued that hired labor would not 
promote the freedom of the individual laborer at all. To the contrary, he guaranteed that the Chinese experience demonstrated that hired 
laborers were as respectful and subordinate to their employers as Confucian standards required. Choosing one’s employer was neither 
to produce freedom of choice in society at large, or to transform laborers into commodities and wage slaves in a capitalist system. 
One of Yu’s overarching themes was the establishment of a truly moral society ruled by moral officials. He denigrated the 
examination system for its failure to producing honest and dedicated officials, but he saw the answer in adapting ancient institutions, 
particularly resuscitating the moribund official school system and initiating the face-to-face evaluation of candidates for office. Yu’s 
ideal society was to be as hierarchical as contemporary Korean society, but on an almost completely different basis – demonstrated 
superiority in Confucian ethical behavior. 
Yu was a defender of popular or peasant welfare, but his sympathies for the common peasants, slaves, lowly clerks, and women 
were often balanced or offset by his commitment to the necessity of hierarchical relations. He sought to level the playing ground by 
having the state confiscate the landed property and reduce the slaves of the yangban and landlords, but he often made certain 
concessions to social reality by accommodating aspects of inherited status that favored members of the noble family, merit subjects 
and their relatives, and the sons of officials without office of their own, and to denigrate nothoi, clerks, slaves, and women. He was 
willing to prolong the period of slavery because he felt that the yangban were emotionally and physically as yet incapable of dispensing 
with their slave labor. At one point, he even assured the yangban families that his reforms would not destroy them because their wealth 
and traditional respect for education would guarantee the success of their sons in his new system of schools. He could make such 
concessions to existing privilege because of his commitment to the propriety of hierarchical respect relations, and his sympathy for the 
members of his own class. 
His plan to refurbish the schools would only have provided for the body of regular officials. He also had to cure the endemic 
corruption of the petty clerks without elevating them to the same level as the regular officials. His solution was to provide them with 
salaries through an improved system of taxation. Whether guaranteed salaries for clerks would have eliminated corruption as Yu hoped 
is something that one can never know because it was never tried, but it would certainly have been an improvement over the existing 
situation. 
Finally, at the lowest end of the bureaucracy, the local district, where the magistrate and his irregular local clerks, village headman, 
and village officials came into direct contact with the people, he hoped to overcome the damage done by corrupt local officials by 
replacing them with semiautonomous institutions like community compacts and village granaries, copied from models created in the 
Sung dynasty, staffed by prominent men of virtue. They were to take charge of teaching villagers and common peasants to practice 
Confucian moral standards, provide mutual aid, relief, and loans, and implement mutual surveillance against criminals and 
wrongdoers. 
Unfortunately, Yu’s plan for the moral reformation of all levels of the bureaucracy was the least effective of all his ideas. The 
examination system was never replaced by a refurbished school system and a serious and sustained method of recommendation. A 
salary system for petty clerks was never instituted to the end of the dynasty, and the community compacts were attempted only in a few 
instances. Only the adoption of village autonomy for the administration of loans was attempted under the Taewongun in the 1860s. 
Otherwise, local nonofficial organizations were dominated almost exclusively by local yangban in protection of their own interests and 
local clerks were left unchecked to profit from bribery. 
Yu’s recommendations for improvements in the economy, particularly the use of metallic cash, did have some influence on the next 
century. When Yu began to write his masterwork around 1650, active officials were already attempting to introduce metallic currency to 
lubricate market transactions. Yu responded to their initiative and sought to add some wisdom to it by consulting the Chinese classics 
and histories. 
Consulting the classics did not necessarily mean that he was conservatively tied to backward economic ideas because what he 
found in those sources was often more developed than contemporary practice in Korea. In fact, Chou China appeared to have had a 
larger commercial sector than Korea, certainly a more advanced use of money. He found that industry and commerce were not evil, as 
some ideologues believed, but necessary for the production and circulation of items of utility among the population. It was just that 
they were secondary to agricultural production and had to be limited lest the attractiveness of profit lured too many peasants from the 
primary occupation of agricultural production. 
Yu agreed with the most progressive Korean officials of his time that market development should be encouraged, certainly as a 
means of reforming the corrupted tribute system. He admired Cho Hŏn’s reports of the more advanced Ming economy, but he did not 
intend to move as far as the Chinese had by allowing sons of merchants to take the examinations. Since he included land allotments for 
merchants in his ideal land distribution scheme, it is obvious that he expected commercial activity only to supplement basic income 
from farming, not replace it. His economic vision was quite a bit behind late Ming economic developments, not to mention earlier 
dynasties. 
Nonetheless, it was his fear of the adverse consequences of inflation because of mistakes in the management of currency in past 
Chinese dynasties that makes him look quite conservative. To be sure, many economists in favor of sound money and stability in the 
twentieth century fear the adverse consequences of inflationary policies, but this concern for stability does not interfere with their 
progressive perspective on the capacity of a healthy capitalist economy to expand steadily. Yu, however, was witnessing the beginnings 
of a cash economy when the mistrust of the value of that cash was powerful. The slightest symptom of inflation was liable to destroy 
confidence in the cash and destroy the whole experiment. For that reason he felt that the only secure way to use cash was to limit its 
type to the penny cash, where the face value was only slightly more than the intrinsic worth of the metal. 
A money system based exclusively on copper pennies was by itself a brake on the potential for expanding the economy. He favored 
it because his economic concepts were tied closely to moral rather than utilitarian objectives. Nickles, dimes, and quarters, let alone 
dollar bills, were not only sure guarantees of inflation, they were also evil seeds that would burgeon into moral decay by stimulating 
greed and avarice, destroying frugality, and leading the peasants to abandon their fields in search of easy profit. 
In short, Yu’s economic thought was progressive by comparison with the relatively backward situation of Korea in the sixteenth 
century, but quite limited with respect to developments in Ming China or Tokugawa Japan, let alone the West. 
 
EIGHTEENTH-CENTURY DEVELOPMENTS 
 
Institutional Changes 
 
There were four major institutional changes in the eighteenth century about which Yu Hyŏngwŏn had something to say: slavery, military 
service, land, and the economy. The reform of the slave system was probably the most significant of any reform in the dynasty. The 
matrilineal succession rule was adopted permanently in 1730, official slaves were abolished in 1801, and the percentage of private slaves 
in the population dropped below 10 percent after 1780, but the abolition of hereditary slavery and of slavery altogether did not occur 
until the end of the nineteenth century. Scholars like Kim Yongsŏp would like to attribute this phenomenon to the emergence of an 
entrepreneurial spirit among the peasantry that allowed slave cultivators to accumulate surpluses and buy their way out of slavery, but 
the concrete evidence for this thesis is weak. Even though the high opportunity cost involved in recapturing runaway slaves and the easy 
economical alternative of replacing slaves with tenants and hired laborers were more likely causes, it is difficult to discount the effect of 
Yu’s direct challenge to slavery on Confucian moral grounds, particularly because his views became widely known among the educated 
class in the late eighteenth century. His contribution to the decline of slavery and Korea as a slave society may be his most outstanding 
contribution to the improvement of Korean life. 
Yu had much less direct influence on the debate over the equal service reform (kyunyŏkpŏp) of 1750, a misnomer if there ever was 
one. Yu’s idea had been to reconstitute and rebuild the military establishment by which the military cloth tax paid by a discrete group of 
support taxpayers would finance rotating duty soldiers. He had also argued for the reintroduction of military affairs into the education 
and training of officials, the adoption of Western firearms, and the reorganization of a defense system. 
By the eighteenth century, however, the Chosŏn military system lost its raison d’être and the military cloth tax became a bane on the 
existence of the commoner peasant. Because of the widespread evasion of registration and service, the shrinking number of commoner 
peasants had to bear the full weight of the military cloth tax. Yu did not anticipate this outcome, but his concern for the maldistribution 
of tax burdens was carried on by many other active officials, who promoted some method of lightening the tax load on commoner 
peasants by shifting slaves to commoner status and including the service-exempt yangban and the legions of tax-evading scholars and 
putative students in the ranks of the support taxpayers. Slaves did escape servitude primarily by running away, but they escaped the net 
of the military service registrars by fair means or foul. The result of three quarters of a century of discussion to extend the military cloth 
tax to yangban was disappointing, however, because King Yŏngjo finally capitulated to their interests and only reduced the tax on 
commoners. The tax reduction had but temporary and limited effects, for by the middle of the nineteenth century it became one of the 
major causes of peasant rebellion. 
Another issue was the land tax, an issue where Yu’s ideas were far beyond the capacity of his age. He had recognized that the 
maldistribution of land, not just the land tax, was the primary cause of peasant poverty in an agrarian society. His appeal for national 
confiscation and redistribution did not elicit much of a response in the seventeenth century because the land tax was still quite light. 
The adoption of the taedongmi rice surtax on land to provide funds to replace local tribute, however, increased the severity of the land 
tax in the structure of taxation. 
Even then the nominal land tax rate still remained relatively low, but the trend toward the concentration of land in the hands of large 
landlords, the loss of land by smallholders, and their decline to landless sharecroppers and laborers exacerbated their economic 
hardship. By the end of the eighteenth century, the time had become ripe for some kind of remedial action. The armchair statecraft 
scholars in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, often referred to as the Sirhak school, were by no means unified on the solution. 
Some like Tasan (Chŏng Yagyong) backed the radical nationalization and redistribution plan, but others like Sŏngho (Yi Ik) opted for a 
more conservative land limitation system than Yu Hyŏngwŏn’s. Most serious officials dismissed redistribution as unrealistic because 
the defense of landed property had become impregnable. The turning point was reached in the 1790s when King Chŏnjo put out a call 
for advice on the land question but he failed to take any serious action to alleviate the problems of land distribution and taxation. The 
land problem carried over into the nineteenth century with disastrous consequences, because it was identified as one of the three major 
causes of the Imsul rebellion of 1862. 
The third of the major causes of that rebellion was the maladministration of credit, loans, and relief handled mainly by district 
magistrates and their clerks. As more peasant smallholders were reduced to the margin of subsistence by the loss of land to landlords 
and then driven over the edge to starvation by natural disaster, they were reduced to dependency on relief payments and loans. Unable 
to repay the loans because of their marginal economic position, the loans were turned over and the interest payments became a 
permanent tax. When rebellion broke out in 1862 the peasants directed their ire against the district magistrates and their clerks, the ones 
responsible for the administration of the land and military service taxes and the collection of interest payments on loans. 
In the recovery plan of the Taewongun in the 1860s, a few of Yu Hyŏngwŏn’s recommendations for action played a small role. His 
plan for nationalization and redistribution was simply ignored, only a half-hearted effort was made to carry out a cadastral survey to 
register cultivated land for fairer collection of the land tax, and his suggestion for the adoption of recommendation in the selection of 
officials was tried as a supplement to the examination system. The Taewongun was the first to mint multiple denomination cash, as the 
more advanced eighteenth century experts on currency had advocated, but that policy was contrary to Yu’s advice to limit metallic 
currency to penny cash. His prediction that it would produce inflation came true. 
On the other hand, his idea of extending military service to all male adults but officials, modified in the course of the debate in the 
eighteenth century to an extension of the military service tax to yangban households, was finally adopted. And his recommendation for 
the transfer of relief and loan administration from the district magistrates to the leadership of prominent gentry was adopted. 
It was not to be expected that Yu’s seventeenth-century perspective would have remained relevant to nineteenth-century 
circumstance, but Yu did inspire a number of well-known reformers in the eighteenth century, and the germ of several of his reform 
ideas was preserved in the frost of two centuries of administrative deterioriation, recalled to life by the Taewongun to save the dynasty 
from collapse. 
 
Commerce and Industry 
 
Yu Hyŏngwŏn learned much from the debate over the emergence of a more active commercial economy in the seventeenth century, and 
he was one of the spokesmen for progress in the context of that time. He expected commerce to play a more active role in the economy 
than in the past century, and he welcomed the introduction of copper cash to promote a more fluid exchange system, but his ideas were 
only known to a few until the turn of the eighteenth century. When they did, some of his ideas that were progressive for the seventeenth 
century had become conservative in the eighteenth. 
The reason was that King Sukchong was unable to manage the currency to prevent inflation in those arteries of trade that used cash, 
and he shut down the mints in frustration. The fear of inflation was inherited by King Yŏngjo in the 1720s, who believed that a return to 
a noncash agrarian economy would be better for the Korean population. The policies of these two kings did not reflect the dominant 
opinion at court. In fact the kings were far less enlightened or progressive than a number of officials, contrary to Kings T’aejong, Sejong, 
and Sejo who unsuccessfully sought to introduce metallic and paper money into Korea in the fifteenth century. Only reluctantly was 
King Yŏngjo persuaded that cash had become a permanent aspect of Korean commerce, and that minting cash was the best way to 
solve the economic bottlenecks created by long-term deflation. 
Even though a number of active officials had become more open and progressive in their attitude toward currency and suggested 
the minting of multiple-denomination and silver cash and paper money, Yŏngjo refused to go beyond penny cash, a policy left intact 
until the Taewongun’s regime in the 1860s. This was essentially the same attitude of Yu Hyŏngwŏn in the mid-1600s, but after currency 
became indispensable to the economy, the fear of inflation and penny cash led to deflation and a serious brake on economic growth. 
The development of commerce had also led to the rise of private, unlicensed merchants and artisans – even members of the official 
establishment who engaged in both private as well as official production of goods – who challenged the licensed monopolies and took 
over an increasing share of the market without government permission. This phenomenon represented a departure from the licensed 
monopoly system of the early Chosŏn dynasty, but government officials tolerated it nonetheless. They did not ban it as an unacceptable 



=====






Read now

No comments: