Explaining Corruption in South Korea,
Relative to Taiwan and the Philippines:
Focusing on the Role of Land Reform and Industrial Policy
Jong-Sung You
Abstract
By comparing
Korea’s relative level of corruption with that of Taiwan and the Philippines
and examining how a political economy of corruption has developed over time
within Korea, I test my “inequality hypothesis” and existing theories on causes
of corruption. I find that inequality of
income and wealth best explains the relative level of corruption among these
countries and across time within Korea, consistent with my hypothesis. Although developmental state and crony
capitalism literature paradoxically emphasize the “autonomous and uncorrupt
bureaucracy” and “rampant cronyism and corruption” in Korea, respectively, I
find that Korea has been neither as corrupt as the Philippines nor as clean as
Taiwan. Successful land reform in Korea
and Taiwan brought about low levels of inequality and corruption, while failure
of land reform in the Philippines led to a high level of inequality and
corruption. Wealth concentration due to
chaebol industrialization, however, increased corruption over time in Korea, in
comparison with Taiwan.
Introduction
South Korea
(Korea hereafter, except occasionally), together with Taiwan, has been praised
by many scholars as a model developmental state with a competent and uncorrupt
bureaucracy (Johnson 1987; Amsden 1989; Evans 1995; Wade 1990). Since the financial crisis of 1997, however,
Korea has often been labeled as an example of crony capitalism, together with
other Asian countries like the Philippines (Kang 2002). Hence, an important question to be resolved
is whether Korea has been as corrupt as the Philippines or relatively clean
like Taiwan.
2
Indeed, Taiwan
and the Philippines are ideal comparison cases.
Korea shares many similarities with Taiwan and the Philippines. The initial economic conditions in the 1950s
and 1960s were not much different among these countries. The three countries all experienced colonial
rule before World War II, and were all heavily supported by the US during the
Cold War era. They all have been
experiencing democratization processes over the last two decades. Despite the similar initial conditions,
however, the levels of corruption and economic development today are quite
different. Taiwan has an obviously lower
level of corruption than the Philippines.
Not only do all the available quantitative measures of (perceived)
corruption indicate that this is the case, but this has not been contradicted
by any qualitative studies, to my knowledge.
Where, then, does Korea fall relative to Taiwan and the Philippines, and
why is that so?
The second set of
questions is about Korea’s corruption trend.
Many scholars, including Alice Amsden (1989) and Peter Evans (1995),
regarded Park Chung-Hee’s regime (1961-79) as a prototype of a developmental
state, while they judged Syngman Rhee’s regime (1948-60) as predatory. Others
such as Andrew Wedeman (1997) and David Kang (2002), however, argued
that both regimes were similarly corrupt.
Thus, the controversy regarding the transition from a predatory state to
a developmental state is another interesting question. Understudied, yet no less important, are the
questions of how industrialization and economic development since the 1960s and
political democratization since 1987 have affected the level of corruption in
Korea.
By corruption, I
mean “abuse of power for private gain.”
There are many kinds of corruption, but this paper will focus on
political corruption and high-level bureaucratic corruption. Although petty corruption may be more
important for the everyday lives of most people, there is evidence that the
degree of petty corruption is closely correlated with the degree of political
and high-level bureaucratic corruption.[1] Also, I use the term capture, which indicates
that corruption has reached to the point in which the state has lost autonomy
and serves for the special interests of the privileged.
My comparative
historical case study of corruption in Korea, relative to Taiwan and the
Philippines, has two purposes. First, I
intend to contribute to a better understanding
of corruption and development in
Korea with a comparative perspective through an extensive and systematic
examination of both quantitative and qualitative evidence.
Second, I aim to
provide a test of my “inequality hypothesis” and existing theories on causes of
corruption. In my article with Sanjeev
Khagram (2005), I presented my theoretical arguments on why economic inequality
should increase corruption and provided supporting evidence through
cross-national statistical analysis. In
particular, I presented quite convincing evidence of causal effect of
inequality on corruption through instrumental variables regressions, using
“mature cohort size” as an instrument for inequality. However, it is always very hard to find a
perfect instrumental variable, and “mature cohort size” may not be a perfect
instrument although I believe it’s a reasonably good instrument. In order to supplement my quantitative study,
I conduct this comparative case study to identify causal direction and casual
mechanisms through process tracing.
Most empirical
studies on the causes of corruption were cross-national statistical
analyses. Although large-N quantitative
studies have an advantage in identifying correlations between an explanatory
variable(s) and the dependent variable controlling for plausible covariates,
and thus may be less vulnerable to omitted variables bias than small-N case
studies, they are often vulnerable to endogeneity bias and weak at identifying
causal mechanisms. Comparative
historical case studies can be useful for establishing causal direction and
illuminating causal mechanisms by examining the historical sequence and
intervening causal process between an independent variable(s) and the outcome
of the dependent variable (Rueschemeyer and Stephens 1997).
This study makes
use of available quantitative and qualitative data from a variety of
sources. Although most data are
secondary, careful examination of extensive data from secondary sources may be
better than the use of limited, and perhaps biased, primary data. I find that Korea has been more corrupt than
Taiwan but much less corrupt than the Philippines. I also find that income and wealth inequality
is closely correlated with the relative levels of corruption among the three
countries. In order to establish causal
direction and identify causal mechanisms, I conduct careful process
tracing. In particular, I discover two
exogenous variables that produced different levels of inequality but were not
affected by corruption in these countries: land reform and industrial
policy. I will show that the success (in
Korea and Taiwan) and failure (in the Philippines) of land reform was primarily
determined by external factors but produced different levels of inequality and corruption
and that different industrial policies created different effects on inequality
and corruption over time in Korea and Taiwan.
The organization
of this chapter is as follows. First, I
briefly review developmental state literature and crony capitalism literature
on Korea’s corruption and development.
In the following sections, I assess various pieces of available evidence
on Korea’s level of corruption relative to Taiwan and the Philippines and its
trend since the 1950s. I then examine
several potential explanations for Korea’s relative level of corruption. In the subsequent sections, I look at how
land reform and chaebol industrialization were carried out in Korea and how
they affected inequality and corruption, in comparison with Taiwan and the
Philippines. I also examine what role
democratization has played in Korea. The
final section summarizes my findings and concludes with research and policy
implications.
Embedded autonomy
or crony capitalism?
Korea’s economy
was regarded as a spectacular success story among developing countries,
together with Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Singapore (World Bank 1993). Although Korea was severely hit by the Asian
financial crisis of 1997-98 and recorded negative growth in 1998, it recovered
rapidly and is growing again. Many
scholars tried to explain Korea’s and these four tigers’ success, and the most
influential explanations were centered on the role of the state (Amsden 1989:
Evans 1995; Wade 1990). They argued that
Korea’s “developmental state” distinguished it from many other developing countries,
which were characterized as “predatory states.”
The developmental states of these four East Asian countries were
coherent and autonomous so that they were able to effectively carry out their
economic policies without degenerating into capture and corruption. The core of the developmental state was
“Weberian bureaucracy” with meritocratic recruitment and promotion, career
service, and reasonable pay and prestige.
Later some South Asian countries such as Thailand, Malaysia, and
Indonesia came to be included in the list of developmental states, although
their growth records were not as fantastic as those of the four East Asian
tigers.
However, the
Asian financial crisis radically changed the perceptions of these countries,
Korea in particular. Many, including the
IMF, blamed the crony capitalism of Korea and other affected countries as
primarily responsible for the crisis.
Thus, overnight, Korea’s image was radically changed from a model
developmental state with good governance to a country with rampant corruption
and cronyism. What, then, is the
truth? Did the proponents of the
developmental state theory fail to see the cronyism and corruption in
Korea? Or did the crony capitalism
argument exaggerate the extent of corruption in Korea? Whereas proponents of the developmental state
theory had to explain why state intervention did not produce much corruption in
Korea, those who argued for crony capitalism had to explain how Korea was able
to achieve rapid economic development in spite of corruption and cronyism.
The government
intervention in the economy meant extensive interaction between public
officials and businessmen. The interaction
could be collaboration, or collusion and corruption, or both. The developmental state argument saw the
close relationship between government and business as benign collaboration, but
the crony capitalism argument interpreted it as collusion and corruption. Peter Evans (1995) argued that collaboration
between the government and business was critically important for development,
because information exchange was necessary for effective policy formation and
implementation, and building up trust helped reduce transaction costs. He
further argued that an autonomous, meritocratic bureaucracy kept collaboration
from degenerating into collusion and corruption. For him, the autonomy of the state requires
insulation of the bureaucracy from powerful societal interests, but insulation
does not mean isolation. Bureaucrats
need to have close ties to business yet still have to formulate and implement
policies autonomously. Thus, “embedded
autonomy” was the key to the effectiveness of the developmental state of Korea,
according to Evans (1995).
Most scholars who
studied the developmental state of Korea regarded Park ChungHee’s regime
(1961-1979) as a prototype of the developmental state. However, Syngman Rhee’s
regime (1948-1960) was generally regarded as predatory. Alice Amsden (1989: 42) characterized the
1950s with corruption, underachievement, and bitter disappointment. Peter Evans (1995:51-52) noted that, under
Syngman Rhee, the civil service exam was largely bypassed and that his
dependence on private-sector donations to finance his political dominance made
him dependent on clientelistic ties and caused rampant rentseeking
activities. Some scholars also noted
that Korea’s developmental state has been challenged and has been weakening
since the 1980s (Moon 1994; Evans 1995).
Other scholars
saw rampant corruption in Korea throughout its history after independence,
including the period of Park Chung-Hee’s presidency, and attempted to reconcile
the high growth and high corruption.
Andrew Wedeman (1997) argued that Korea has had widespread, high-level
corruption ever since 1945 but that the type of corruption in Korea was
functional for economic development. He
distinguished three different types of corruption such as looting,
rent-scraping, and dividend-collecting.
Korea’s corruption represented an ideal type of dividend-collection,
while the Philippines and Zaire are examples of rent-scraping and looting,
respectively. Looting means uninhibited
plundering or systematic theft of public funds and property and extraction of
bribes by public officials.
Rent-scraping means conscious manipulation of macroeconomic parameters
to produce rents and the scraping off of these rents by public officials. Dividend-collecting means transfers of a
percentage of the profits earned by privately owned enterprises to government
officials. Among the three types of
corruption, looting is the most harmful to the economy while
dividend-collecting may be functional for economic development. The Korean governments, he argued, sold economic
opportunities and collected some portion of the profits, and their corrupt
income stayed in Korea rather than going into Swiss bank accounts.
David Kang (2002)
also saw cronyism and corruption throughout the history of South
Korea. He compared crony capitalism in Korea and the
Philippines, and argued that Korea neither had a more autonomous or coherent
state nor was subject to any less corruption than the Philippines but that
corruption had different effects on development in the two countries. He argued that the types of corruption and
their effects on economic growth vary depending on whether the state is coherent or fractured and whether
the business sector is concentrated or dispersed. It is different types of corruption rather
than different levels of corruption that lead to different effects on economic
development. According to him, Korea was
under a situation of “mutual hostages” between the
coherent state and the concentrated business during Park Chung-Hee and Chun DooWhan era and cronyism helped reduce transaction costs and minimize deadweight losses, whereas in the Philippines corruption
deterred economic growth because corruption allowed “rent-seeking” activities
of the business (pre-Marcos) and “predatory” behavior of the state (under
Marcos). He
further argues that the Philippines was less affected by the crisis of 1997
because some of the collusive government-business ties had been broken by the
downfall of Marcos, while democratization in Korea increased rent-seeking
activities and hence made it more vulnerable to the crisis.
Korea’s level of
corruption, relative to Taiwan and the Philippines
In this paper, I
focus on identifying and explaining the relative level of corruption in Korea
rather than types of corruption. It is
very hard to compare the levels of corruption across countries. Corruption, by its nature, is conducted
secretly, and the probability of exposure will be different in different
countries. Hence, most empirical studies
of corruption rely on measures of the “perceived” level of corruption such as
Transparency International’s (TI) Corruption Perceptions Index (CPI) and
Kaufmann et al.’s (2003)
Control of Corruption Indicator
(CCI). TI has been publishing the CPI
annually since 1995, and the CCI has been released since 1996.
Both the CPI
and the CCI are aggregate indices based on a variety of surveys of mostly
international business people and ratings of country experts, although there
are some methodological differences in aggregating various underlying survey
data as well as some differences in the selection of sources. Because perceptions are subjective and
inaccurate, these indices must have substantial measurement error. They are highly correlated with each other,
however, and also are highly correlated with domestic public perceptions of
corruption.[2]
Figure 1 shows
the point estimates and 95 percent confidence intervals of the CCI 2002 for
several Asian countries. A higher CCI value represents a higher level of
control of corruption, or a lower level of corruption. Because the CCI is a standardized score with
a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 1, it is easy to interpret the CCI
value in comparison to the world average.
Figure 1.
In 2002, Korea’s
CCI value was 0.33, so its level of corruption was about a third standard
deviation below the world mean among the 195 countries that were covered in the
CCI 2002. Taiwan’s CCI 2002 value was 0.81, so corruption in Taiwan was about
four fifths of a standard deviation below the world mean. The Philippines’s CCI 2002 value was -0.52,
so its level of corruption was about a half standard deviation above the world
average. When we compare CCI 2002 values
of Korea, Taiwan, and the Philippines, Korea’s level of corruption was much
lower than that of the Philippines, but higher than that of Taiwan.
Table 1 presents
the available measures of corruption for Korea, Taiwan, and the Philippines for
the early 1980s to the present. CPI
80-85 and CPI 88-92 are TI’s historical data, and CPI 95-07 and CCI 96-06 are
averaged values for the period. BI 8083
denotes Business International’s data.
Both CPI and BI range from 1 to 10, and a higher value represents a
lower level of corruption. While all
these data are measures of the perceived level of freedom from corruption,
Bribery 04-06 from TI’s Global Corruption Barometer Survey (average for
2004-2006) is a measure of the experience of corruption. The Barometer survey asked the respondents,
“In the past 12 months, have you or anyone living in your household paid a
bribe in any form?” The respondents
answered either “Yes” or “No.” Four
percent of Korean respondents said, “Yes,”[3] whereas two percent of
Taiwanese and fifteen percent of Filipinos gave the same answer.
Table 1. Indicators of (Freedom from) Corruption for
the Three Countries
Sources: BI’s ratings from Mauro (1995); CPI and Bribery from
Transparency
International;
CCI from D.
Kaufmann, A. Kraay, and M. Mastruzzi (2007).
The experience of
bribery (Bribery 04-06) from the Barometer survey is a good objective measure
of corruption comparable across countries.
One caveat is that this measure is likely to capture petty corruption
very well but may be a poor measure of grand corruption. However, there are reasons to believe that
the levels of petty corruption and the levels of grand corruption are closely
correlated, because corrupt practices are likely to spread both top-down and
bottom-up. Moreover, the public
experience of bribery (Bribery 04-06) is highly correlated with the CPI and the
CCI.[4]
Because the CPI and the CCI are more
likely to reflect corruption at the upper level of bureaucracy and political
corruption rather than petty corruption, the assumption of a close correlation
between petty corruption and high-level corruption seems to hold in
reality.
All the data
presented above consistently show that Korea has been more corrupt than Taiwan
but less corrupt than the Philippines at least since the early 1980s.[5] Unfortunately, there are no available
quantitative measures of corruption comparable across these countries for an
earlier period. Table 1, however,
suggests that the same relative rankings are very likely to apply for the 1970s
and probably for even earlier periods as well, unless there are important
reasons for radical changes in the levels of corruption during the earlier
period.
Anecdotal
evidence also suggests that political corruption in Korea was higher than that
in Taiwan but lower than that in the Philippines. In Korea, two former presidents, Chun
Doo-Whan and Roh Tae-Woo, were found guilty of corruption. Chun and Roh were accused of raising slush
funds of $890 million and $654 million and of receiving $273 million and $396
million in bribery, respectively. The
Philippines’s Ferdinand Marcos was known to have accumulated $3 billion, and
was found to have used several million dollars to buy foreign real estate,
primarily in New York, and to have deposited around $550 million and $250
million in Swiss banks and Hong Kong banks, respectively (Wedeman 1997). Considering that the Philippine GDP was much
smaller than that of
Korea in the 1980s, Marcos’s
corruption was much more severe that that of the two Korean presidents. Although Taiwan has had many scandals of
political corruption, too, there was no such big corruption scandal comparable
to Marcos’s or Chun’s and Roh’s.
In summary, the
evidence indicates that the developmental state literature generally overlooks
the problem of corruption in Korea, while the crony capitalism literature tends
to overestimate the degree of corruption in Korea.
Korea’s level of
corruption, from the 1950s to the present
Now, what can we
say about the trend of corruption in Korea across time? Was the level of corruption higher in the
1950s, under Syngman Rhee, than in the 1960s and 1970s, under Park
Chung-Hee? Did corruption increase or
decrease with the rapid industrialization and economic growth in the 1970s and
the 1980s? Has the level of corruption
increased or decreased since the democratization of 1987?
There are no
quantitative data available that are comparable across the three countries for
the period before 1980, to my knowledge.
Previous literature, especially developmental state literature, often
assumed without presenting adequate evidence that Rhee’s regime was highly
corrupt but Park’s regime was not. This
judgment seems to be based on reasoning that Park’s regime must have been less
corrupt than Rhee’s because Korea’s economy developed very fast under Park, and
did not under Rhee. Several scholars,
however, including John Lie (1998), Andrew Wedeman (1999), and David Kang
(2002) judged that Park’s regime was not considerably less corrupt than Rhee’s
based on various pieces of anecdotal evidence.
Some Korean scholars also argued that the Rhee and Park regimes cannot
be differentiated in terms of the degree of rent-seeking and corruption (Kim
and Im 2001), and that Park’s centrally managed economy produced a large scope
for rent-seeking and corruption (Lee 1995).
In the mid-1970s, a Korean social scientist noted that “the rapid
expansion of the scope of governmental authority (under Park) tended to induce
corruption at a far greater scale and in an even more pervasive manner than
before (under Rhee)” (Hahn 1975). Many
journalistic reports on corruption during the Park administration argued, with
some quantitative and qualitative evidence, that the level of corruption then
was no smaller, and possibly larger, than under Rhee (Lee and Kim 1964; Park
1967).
It is true that
one of Park’s rationales for the military coup in 1961 was to eliminate
corruption, as Chun Doo-Whan’s military coup of 1980 also used that same
catchphrase. Immediately after the coup
of May 16, 1961, the military junta arrested chaebol owners on charges of
illicit wealth accumulation, but the investigation ended with a negotiation on
the political and economic terms between the military and business owners. The junta not only reduced the fines for
illicit wealth accumulation, but also provided financial subsidies for those
industrialists who pledged to undertake specific industrial projects and to
provide political funds (Kim and Im 2001).
Because of
international and domestic pressures, Park had to end military rule in two
years and run for presidential election in 1963. He created the Democratic Republican Party
(DRP), and needed funds to support the party and expensive campaigning. It was widely known that the inaugural fund
for the party was prepared by illegal manipulation of the stock market (Oh and
Sim 1995:248). He even received secret
donations from Japanese and American firms.
It is estimated that Park spent about 60 billion won (approximately $200
million) for the election, while the total amount of official contributions
from businesses was just 30 million won (approximately $100,000) (Woo 1991:107;
Oh and Sim 1995:275-76). This indicates
that the bulk of political funds were collected in illegal ways.
An important
conduit of political funds during Park’s regime came from the allocation of
foreign loans with low interest rates, for which the recipients were happy to
pay a commission of 10 to 15 percent.
Other sources of political contributions included quid pro quos for
granting low-interest loans and for procurement of government projects (Woo
1991:108; Kim and Park 1968).
Is it possible,
then, to assess the degree of corruption under Park in comparison with that
under Rhee, Chun, and Roh? One way of
accomplishing that is by looking at the amount of illicitly raised political
funds during their presidencies. It is
quite certain that the total amount of illicitly collected political funds has
increased over time from Syngman Rhee (1948-1960) to Park Chung-Hee (1961-1979)
to Chun Doo-Whan (198187) to Roh Tae-Woo (1988-92), if not to Kim Young-Sam
(1993-97). Individual contributions also increased over time. Five chaebol were found to have made more
than 60 million won (about 1.5 billion won in 1990 constant prices) of informal
political contributions to Rhee’s Liberal Party (Kim 1964). Top businessmen’s annual contributions to
Park are known to have reached 500 to 600 million won (about 1.3 to 1.5 billion
won in 1990 constant prices), starting from 100 to 200 million won (about 0.8
to
1.5 billion won in 1990 constant
prices) before Yushin (in 1972)[6]
and 200 to 300 million won (about 1 to 1.5 billion won in 1990 constant prices)
in the early Yushin period (Oh and Sim 1995:253). Samsung, Hyundai, Tonga, and Daewoo were
found to have made illegal political donations of between 15 and 22 billion won
to President Chun during seven years of his presidency, and Samsung, Hyundai,
Daewoo and LG illegally contributed between 21 and 25 billion won to President
Roh Tae-Woo during five years of his presidency. Also, Samsung was found to have donated
illegally at least 10 billion won and 34 billion won (8 and 22 billion won in
1990 constant prices) in the 1997 and 2002 presidential elections,
respectively, to Lee Hoi-Chang, who lost to Kim Dae-Jung and Roh Moo-Hyun,
respectively (PSPD 2005).[7]
Chung Ju-Young, the founder of the Hyundai Group, once declared that he donated
to Roh Tae-Woo 2 to 3 billion won twice each year, and even 10 billion won in
1992, the last year of Roh’s office.
Finally, Chung Tae-Soo, the founder of the Hanbo Group, was found to
have donated 60 billion won to Kim Young-Sam before the presidential election
of 1992 (Oh and Sim 1995: 274).[8] It is notable that Hanbo Group went bankrupt
in early 1997, which was the first of a series of chaebol failures that led
Korea to financial and economic crisis.
Top-level businessmen’s informal political donations seemed to have
steadily increased over time from the 1950s until the early 1990s. Considering all these available pieces of
evidence, it is hard to tell that Park’s regime was essentially less corrupt
than Rhee’s.
So far, we
primarily looked at political corruption.
Tae-beom Yoon (1994) looked at bureaucratic corruption in the Third
Republic (Park’s regime before the Yushin: 1963-72), Fourth Republic (Park’s
regime after the Yushin: Oct. 1972-1979), fifth Republic (Chun’s regime:
1982-87), and the sixth Republic (Roh’s regime: 1988-1992). He searched corruption-related articles from
the three major newspapers (Dongailbo, Chosunilbo, and Choongangilbo) during
the two years, except the last year, in the later period of each Republic. Political corruption was excluded from his
analysis, because media reports of political corruption depend very much on the
degree of freedom of press rather than the actual incidence of corruption.
Table 2 shows the
number of media-reported bureaucratic corruption incidents for each Republic by
the amount of bribes paid in 1985 constant prices, based on Yoon (1994). The number of reported corruption incidents
is not significantly different among the Republics. Considering that freedom of the press was
most severely suppressed in the fourth Republic (Park’s regime after the
Yushin), it is surprising that the number of corruption incidents of over 10
million won during the 4th Republic is no less than that during the
5th Republic. Yoon’s (1994)
research did not include the First Republic (Rhee’s regime: 1948-1960) and the
short-lived Second Republic (Chang Myun administration: 1960-61). Although we cannot tell whether bureaucratic
corruption was lower under Park than under Rhee, it was not markedly lower than
under Chun or Roh.
Table 2. Number of
Bureaucratic Corruption Incidents Reported in the Media, by the Amount of Bribe in 1985
Constant Prices
|
3rd Rep. Park (61-72) |
4th Rep. Park (72-79) |
5th Rep. Chun (80- 87) |
6th Rep. Roh (88-92) |
1-10 million won |
31 |
30 |
56 |
16 |
> 10 million won |
10 |
22 |
21 |
34 |
Total |
41 |
52 |
77 |
50 |
Source: Yoon (1994)
Note:
The period covered for each Republic is as follows. Dec.1969 through Nov. 1971
(3rd Rep.), Aug. 1977 through Jul. 1979 (4th Rep.), Dec. 1984
through Nov. 1986 (5th Rep.), and Feb. 1990 through Jan. 1992 (6th
Rep.).
Considering all
the evidence presented so far, it is very likely that Park’s regime was not
substantially different from Rhee’s, Chun’s, or Roh’s in terms of degree of
overall corruption, except for Chun’s and Roh’s personal accumulation of wealth
during their presidencies. Table 3
summarizes the comparable information across presidencies, and it is hard to
identify any qualitatively important differences in the level of political and
bureaucratic corruption among various regimes.
The primary difference between Rhee and Park was more about competence
rather than about corruption. The
overall level of corruption seems to have slightly increased until the early
1990s, and it has been slightly decreasing since the late 1990s.
Table 3. Various Information about Corruption across
Presidencies
President |
Period |
CPI |
# of reported bureaucratic
corruption** |
Top-level political donation*** (1990 constant billion won) |
|
* |
|
||||
Rhee Syngman |
1948- 1960 |
|
|
|
1.5-3.5 (five chaebol) |
Park Chung-Hee |
1961- 1972 |
|
|
41 |
5-10 (estimated) |
Park Chung-Hee |
1972- 1979 |
|
|
52 |
7-10 (estimated) |
Chun Doo-Whan |
1980- 1987 |
|
3.9 |
77 |
16-24 (four chaebol) |
Roh Tae-Woo |
1988- 1992 |
|
3.5 |
50 |
21-25 (four chaebol) |
Kim Young-Sam |
1993- 1997 |
|
4.3 |
|
56 (Hanbo) |
Kim Dae-Jung |
1998- 2002 |
|
4.2 |
|
8 to Lee (Samsung) |
Roh Moo-Hyun |
2003- |
|
4.8 |
|
22 to Lee (Samsung) |
2007
Sources:
* TI, ** Yoon (1994), *** Kim (1964), Oh and Sim (1995), and PSPD (2005). For
Park’s periods of before and after the Yushin, the presented values are
estimated from the typical top-level annual political donation. All other
values are based on the prosecution’s findings.
Explanations for
South Korea’s relative level of corruption
Why, then, has
Korea been more corrupt than Taiwan but less corrupt than the Philippines, even
though the three countries shared similar initial conditions in many aspects? In order to explain Korea’s relative level of
corruption in comparison with Taiwan and the Philippines, I will first consider
the explanatory ability of several factors such as government intervention,
economic development, income inequality, democracy, Protestantism,
Confucianism, and ethnic homogeneity that have been proposed by the literature
to have positive or negative causal effects on corruption.
The degree of
government intervention in the economy, or the size of government is often
regarded as a cause of corruption, because government intervention can create
rents and encourage rent-seeking activities.
Recent empirical findings, however, show that larger government size is
associated with lower levels of corruption (La Porta et al, 1999; Friedman et
al, 2000). In our case, the degree of
government intervention does not seem to explain the relative levels of
corruption in the three countries.
Governments in Korea and Taiwan intervened in the economy very heavily,
but the levels of corruption were lower in these countries than in the
Philippines where government intervention was not as extensive as in Korea or
Taiwan. It may be more useful to look at
what kinds of government intervention increase corruption under what conditions
than just the overall extent of government intervention. I will attempt to do so in the following
sections.
The level of
economic development (per capita income), perhaps through the spread of
education, creation of a middle class, and so forth, has been found by many
empirical studies to have the most significant and important explanatory power
for corruption (Paldam 2002; Treisman 2000).
In contrast, Kaufmann and Kraay (2002) argue that causation runs in the
opposite direction: from lower corruption to economic development. You and Khagram (2005) also showed that
previous studies overestimated the effect of economic development on
corruption. The case of the three
countries seems to support the argument of Kaufmann and Kraay (2002).
Economic
development cannot explain the relative levels of corruption in the three
countries, considering that the initially no-less-developed Philippines has
become much more corrupt than Korea and Taiwan.
Table 4 indicates that the Philippines had a slightly higher per capita
income in the 1950s and not much lower per capita income than Korea and Taiwan
until 1980. It is more likely that
different levels of corruption seem to explain the variations in economic
growth in these countries. However, we
may need to consider more complex relationships between corruption and economic
development beyond simple causation in either direction. In particular, some government policies may
affect both corruption and economic growth at the same time. I will examine this possibility in later
sections.
Table 4. Real GDP per capita
in 1996 constant $
year |
1953 |
1968 |
1980 |
1996 |
S. Korea |
1328 |
2289 |
4790 |
14320 |
Philippines |
1571 |
2343 |
3289 |
3122 |
Taiwan |
1118 |
2399 |
5869 |
15589 |
Source: Heston et
al. (2002)
Although
democracy is theoretically supposed to provide checks against corruption,
cross-national empirical studies have found differing results. Treisman (2000) concludes that democracies
are significantly less corrupt only after 40 years. Montinola and Jackman (2002) demonstrate that
partial democratization may increase corruption, but that once past a
threshold, democracy inhibits corruption. Another quite opposite argument to
consider is the positive role of authoritarian regimes in controlling corruption. Lee Kwan Yew of Singapore claims that
authoritarian rule there has been necessary to contain corruption as well as to
help develop the economy. Taiwan’s
Chiang Ching-Kuo and Korea’s Park Chung-Hee were also cited as such
examples.
In terms of democracy,
Korea and the Philippines have many similarities. Both countries initially had democratic
period until 1972 (pre-Yushin period except for 196163 in Korea, and
pre-Marshall Law period in the Philippines), and had a dramatic and rapid
democratic transition from 1986 (the Philippines) or 1987 (Korea). Taiwan had
an authoritarian regime until the late 1980s and since then has gradually
democratized. Thus, among the three
countries, Taiwan has been the least democratic until recently, but also the
least corrupt. This seems to support the
argument of Lee Kwan Yew. However,
corruption has apparently decreased rather than increased after democratic
transition in these countries. Table 1
shows that the values of the CPI 95-07 are slightly higher than those of the
CPI 88-92 for all three countries.[9]
Ethno-linguistic
fractionalization has been found to be positively correlated with corruption,
although its significance disappears after per capita income and latitude
controls are added (Mauro 1995; La Porta et al. 1999). As Table 5 shows, Korea has an extremely high
level of homogeneity both ethnically and linguistically, but corruption is
higher in Korea than in ethnically and linguistically heterogeneous Taiwan. Although the extremely high linguistic
fractionalization may partly explain the high level of corruption in the
Philippines, the ethno-linguistic story does not fit very well for our case of
the three countries overall.
Protestantism has
been found by many cross-country empirical studies to be associated
significantly with less corruption (La Porta et al. 1999; Paldam 2001;
Sandholtz and Koetzle 2000; Treisman 2000).
Egalitarian or individualistic religions such as Protestantism may
encourage challenges to abuses by officeholders. Table 5 shows that, in terms of
Protestantism, Korea has some advantage, not disadvantage, over Taiwan, but
Protestantism does not seem to have much contributed to lowering corruption in
Korea. There may be a threshold for the
Protestantism effect, and Korea’s Protestant population may not have reached
the threshold.
Table 5. Ethnic and Linguistic Fractionalization;
Percentage Population by Religion in 1980
|
Ethnic frac. |
Linguistic frac.
|
Protestant |
Catholic |
Muslim |
Buddhist |
S. Korea |
0.002 |
0.002 |
12.2 |
3.9 |
0 |
20* |
Taiwan |
0.27 |
0.5 |
3 |
1.5 |
0.5 |
93** |
Philipp |
0.24 |
0.84 |
3.8 |
84.1 |
4.3 |
3*** |
ines
Source:
Ethnic and linguistic fractionalization is from Alesina et al. (2003). Percentage population by religion (for year
1980), except for the Buddhist population, is from La Porta et al. (1999). For the Buddhist population,
* for year 1985, from Ministry of Economic Planning, Korea's Social
Indicators 1987 **mixture of Buddhist, Confucian, and Taoist 93%, from CIA
Factbook, 2004 *** Buddhist and other,
from CIA Factbook, 2004.
“Confucian familism” has often been accused of
fostering patrimony, nepotism, social distrust, and bribes or gift exchanges
(Fukuyama 1995; Kim 1999), and crony capitalism literature has often relied on
these arguments (Kim and Im 2001). It is
questionable, however, whether nepotism and gift exchange is unique to
Confucian cultures. Tu (2001) argues
that Confucian literati tried to curb a king’s despotism and bureaucratic
corruption and that Confucian familism is not the same as cronyism. A study of Korean social networks (Yee 2000)
demonstrates that, contrary to Fukuyama’s view that Koreans under the Confucian
influence are more kin-oriented, they actually rely less on their kin than
Americans do.
Confucian
tradition is very strong in Korea and Taiwan, while it is absent in the
Philippines; the meritocratic bureaucracies in Korea and Taiwan actually have
their historical roots in Confucian tradition (Evans 1995; Schneider and
Maxfield 1997). Korea and Taiwan,
however, are much less corrupt than the Philippines. Thus, the Confucian familism
argument seems to lack solid evidence.
Note that the developmental state literature emphasizes the positive
role of meritocratic bureaucracy in ensuring the autonomy of the state and
preventing it from degenerating into collusion and corruption.
Lastly, You and
Khagram (2005) argued that income inequality increases the level of
corruption. The wealthy have greater
resources that can be used for corruption, and their incentives for buying
political influence through corruption increases as redistributive pressures
grow with inequality. Since higher
levels of inequality—and, in particular, more skewed income distributions—mean
lower ratios of median income to mean income, redistributive pressures should
increase as inequality rises, as the median voter theorem predicts (Meltzer and
Richard 1981). Contrary to the
prediction of the median voter theorem, however, we do not observe higher
redistribution in countries with higher inequality (Iversen and Soskice 2002),
probably because policy outcomes favor the rich rather than the median voter
because of corruption. Through a
comparative analysis of 129 countries using instrumental variables regressions,
You and Khagram (2005) demonstrated that the explanatory power of inequality is
at least as important as conventionally accepted causes of corruption such as
economic development.
Income inequality
seems to provide a plausible explanation for the relative levels of corruption
among the three countries. As Table 6
indicates, Korea has had a much more equal distribution of income than the Philippines
ever since the 1950s. Although income
inequality in Korea was as low as in Taiwan until the 1960s, it has become
somewhat higher than in Taiwan since the 1970s.
Thus, the different levels of income inequality may explain the
different levels of corruption in these countries.
Table 6. Inequality in Income and Land in the Three
Countries
Gini(57-69)
Gini(70-89) Gini(90-97) Landgini(60-70)
Korea 26.3 30.6 32.7 37.9
Taiwan 28.3 26.3 27.7
Philippines 43.8 42.2 42.9 52.2
Source:
Gini data are from Dollar and Kraay (2002), adjusted for different definitions
of gini according to You and Khagram (2005); Landgini data are from Taylor and
Jodice (1983).
Table 7
summarizes the discussion so far. As the
table demonstrates, income inequality has the strongest predicting ability for
the levels of corruption. Reverse
causality must be considered, however, as well.
The different levels of corruption could explain the different levels of
inequality. In order to sort out the
causal direction and its mechanisms, we need to figure out why three countries
came to have different degrees of income inequality and how inequality and
corruption affected each other more concretely.
Table 7. Predictive Ability
of Possible Causes of Corruption
Independent variables |
Ranking of the independent variables |
Predicted ranking of corruption |
Match or Not? |
Government intervention |
KOR=TWN > PHL |
KOR=TWN > PHL |
No |
Econ development |
KOR= TWN = PHL (until 1970s) |
KOR= TWN = PHL |
No |
Democracy |
KOR=PHL>=TWN |
KOR=PHL<=TWN |
No |
Ethno-linguistic diversity |
PHL=TWN > KOR |
PHL=TWN > KOR |
No |
Protestantism |
KOR> TWN = PHL |
KOR<= TWN = PHL |
No |
Confucianism |
KOR= TWN > PHL |
KOR= TWN > PHL |
No |
Inequality |
PHL > KOR > TWN |
PHL > KOR > TWN |
Yes |
One plausible
explanation for different levels of income inequality between Korea and Taiwan
on the one hand and the Philippines on the other hand is land reform (Haggard
1990; Rodrik 1995; You 1998). It is well
known that land reform was successful in Korea, Taiwan, and Japan after World
War II, but failed in the Philippines.
It is evident that successes and failures in land reform affected the
subsequent distribution of income.
Why did land
reform succeed in Korea and Taiwan but fail in the Philippines even though the
United States was deeply involved in the land reform processes and exerted
considerable influence in all three countries?
One possible explanation is that very high levels of corruption in the
Philippines inhibited land reform.
Another possible explanation is that different levels of corruption had
little, if any, effect on the success or failure of land reforms, but other
factors determined the fate of land reforms.
Regarding land
reform, another important question should be addressed. Land reform involves massive intervention of
governments in the redistribution of land.
It is very possible, then, that the process of land reform is corrupted
and that land reform contributes to increasing, rather than decreasing,
corruption.
The higher levels
of income inequality in Korea compared to Taiwan since the 1970s may be due to
different strategies and processes of industrialization (Haggard 1990). One plausible hypothesis is that Korea’s
chaebol-centered economy produced higher inequality as well as more incentives
and opportunities for corruption than Taiwan’s economy, centered on small- and
medium-sized firms. Why, then, did Korea
and Taiwan choose different industrialization strategies? One possible explanation is that different
levels of corruption influenced government decision-making in different
ways. Hence, in order to find the right
answers for these questions, the next sections will be devoted to looking at
the decision-making and implementation processes of land reform and industrial
policy in Korea, in comparison with Taiwan and the Philippines.
Land reform
Many accounts of
Korean development tend to ignore agrarian land reform and begin their story
from the early 1960s (Lie 1998). Without
land reform, however, the Korean state might have been captured by the landlord
class and the later economic miracle might not have occurred. In 1945, when Korea was liberated from
Japanese colonial rule, the richest 2.7 percent of rural households owned two
thirds of all the cultivated lands, while 58 percent owned no land at all. By 1956, the top 6 percent owned only 18
percent of the cultivated lands. Tenancy
dropped from 49 percent to 7 percent of all farming households, and the area of
cultivated land under tenancy fell from 65 percent to 18 percent (Ban, Moon,
and Perkins 1980; Lie 1998; Putzel 1992).
Land reform in South Korea was carried out in two stages: by the
American Military
Government (AMG) in 1948 and by the
South Korean government from 1950 to 1952.
In March 1948, the AMG began to distribute 240,000 hectares of former
Japanese lands to former tenants, which accounted for 11.7 percent of total
cultivated land. Before that, the AMG
implemented the reduction of rent, limiting it to one third of crops in October
1945. After two separate governments
were set up in the southern and northern parts of Korea, the government of
South Korea began to implement agrarian land reform in 1950, just before the
Korean War broke out. Restricting the
upper ceiling of landownership to three hectares, the government redistributed
330,000 hectares of farmland by 1952.
The landlords received 1.5 times the annual value of all crops, and the
former tenants were to pay the same amount in five years. About 500,000 hectares were sold directly by
landlords to their tenants. Thus, 52
percent of total cultivated land transferred ownership, and the “principle of
land to tillers” was realized (Ban et al. 1980; Chun 2001; Kim 2001; Putzel
1992).
In Taiwan, land
reform was also extensively carried out in three stages: first, in 1949, rent
reduction to 37.5 percent from the previous 50 percent or over; second, in
1950, sale of public lands to farmers; third, in 1953, land-to-the-tiller
program (Lamba and Tomar 1986). Absentee
ownership was abolished, and a low ceiling was imposed on land that could be
retained by landlords. The compensation
was based on the production value of the land, and landlords received 2.5 times
the annual value of all crops (Putzel 1992).
In the
Philippines, however, land reform has been an abortive issue since before World
War II. All Filipino presidential
candidates since the 1950s have run on platforms offering vague promises of
land reform, but reform has never been pursued with vigor (Kang 2002). Magsaysay’s moderate proposal of land reform
legislation was amended by Congress so that most of the large estates could
easily avoid expropriation. Marcos’s
land reform was minimal, and even Aquino’s reform was quite limited (Doronila
1992; Putzel 1992).
Why, then, did Korea and Taiwan carry out extensive land reform,
whereas the
Philippines did
not? I offer three explanations. The threats from North Korea and
Communist China played a major role
in promoting land reform in South Korea and Taiwan, respectively. The role of the United States in land reform
was positive and liberal in South Korea and Taiwan, but largely conservative in
the Philippines (Putzel 1992). In
addition, the political influence of the landed class was stronger in the
Philippines, while the landlords in Korea and Taiwan lost their influence after
independence because of their collaboration with the Japanese (Evans
1995:51-55).
An overview of the decision-making and implementation processes
within the US
State Department
and the American Military Government (AMG) in Korea and within
Rhee’s government reveals that the
communist threat and the political competition with North Korea to win the
support of peasants played a decisive role in pushing for a liberal reform
program and that the US exerted a positive and liberal influence. Before the US forces arrived in Korea,
“People’s Committees” led by communists and the left-of-center nationalists had
been established throughout the country.
Although the Committees were outlawed by the AMG in the South, they
implemented an extensive land reform in the North as early as March 1946. The North Korean reform was a major factor in
winning support and legitimacy for the newly emerging communist
government. There was a debate between
the liberals and conservatives within the State Department about land reform in
Japan and Korea, and the liberal approach won the debate. In September 1946, the State Department
announced that one of the AMG’s major objectives was to implement land
reform. The implementation of
redistribution of former Japanese-owned land by the AMG was delayed, however,
until March 1948 because of initial reluctance of the Military Governor,
General Lerch. The price of the land was
to be paid at 20 percent of the produce per year for 15 years (Chun 2001;
Putzel 1992).
When the first
election was held for the Republic of Korea in the South in 1948, all parties
pledged to implement land reform and the Constitution included a commitment to
land reform. Even the Korea Democratic
Party that represented the interests of landlords did not openly object to land
reform, but tried to delay the enactment and implementation of the reform and
to increase the compensation for the landlords.
Cho Bong-Am, Minister of Agriculture, drafted a progressive land reform
law with compensation of 150 percent of annual produce. Although there was an attempt to increase the
compensation to 300 percent, the bill was passed with the clause of 150 percent
compensation for the landlords and 125 percent payment for the former tenants
after intense debate in April 1949.
President Rhee vetoed it, however, on the ground that the government could
not finance the 25 percent gap between the compensation and payment. Finally, the Assembly passed the Land Reform
Act with 150 percent of compensation and payment on February 2, 1950, and
President Rhee signed it on March 10, 1950 (Kim 2001).
Unlike in the Philippines, the representatives of the landed class
in the National
Assembly did not have strong power
because of their former collaboration with the Japanese and even the
conservatives agreed that land reform would be necessary to cope with the
communist threat. An interesting phenomenon
in Korea’s land reform was that many landlords sold their land directly to
their tenants before the land reform legislation was implemented. The total area sold by landlords (500,000
hectares) exceeded the area of land redistributed by the government (330,000
hectares), and the bulk of the sell-out occurred in 1948 and 1949 when the
prospect of land reform was clear (Hong 2001).
Taiwan’s case
also demonstrates the important role of Communist China and the liberal
reformers of the US State Department. When Japanese colonial domination of Taiwan
(1895-1945) ended with the defeat of Japan in the World War II, Taiwan reverted
to Chinese rule in 1945. The Nationalist
Chinese administration on Taiwan was initially repressive and corrupt, and the
February uprising in 1947 was violently suppressed by Nationalist Chinese
troops. When Chiang Kai-Shek was
defeated by Mao Tse-Tung’s agrarian revolution on the Chinese mainland, some 2
million predominantly military and bureaucratic refugees fled to Taiwan. Even before Chiang Kai-Shek established his
“provisional” capital in Taipei in December 1949, the Nationalist authorities
began implementing the rent reduction program.
It is notable that Chiang Kai-Shek’s Kuomintang (KMT) and the United
States jointly set up the Joint Commission of Rural Reconstruction in October
1948, in a belated effort to introduce agrarian reform in mainland China (Lamba
and Tomar 1986; Putzel 1992).
Chiang Kai-Shek’s
corrupt and conservative KMT in mainland China transformed itself into a more
coherent and autonomous party-state in Taiwan and embraced land reform,
apparently having been taught a bitter lesson from its failure (Evans
1995:54). The US also advocated liberal
agrarian reform to counter communism, and Ladejinsky, a liberal reformer in the
State Department, worked closely with KMT officials in Taiwan (Putzel
1992). In addition, unlike in mainland
China, the KMT received little resistance from the landed elites in Taiwan.
In the
Philippines, the politics of land reform were more complex. During the US colonial period (1898-1941),
the Americans were not interested in transforming the existing Philippine power
structures through land reform. The Americans,
from William Taft (the first civilian governor) to General Douglas MacArthur,
felt most comfortable with those landed, educated elites who spoke English
(Kang 2002:27).
After the
Philippines gained independence in 1946, the US still exerted enormous
political influence. Just as the State
Department advised liberal land reform in Korea, Taiwan, and Japan, it once did
the same in the Philippines. In 1951,
the US Mutual Security Agency commissioned Robert Hardie to study the tenancy
problem in the Philippines, probably because of growing concern over the rise
of an armed and communist-led peasant movement.
Hardie’s report released in December 1952 contained far-reaching,
comprehensive land reform proposals such as distributing land to 70 percent of
the tenants in the country (Putzel 1992: 84-85).
The landlords and
their representatives in Congress strongly resisted, however, and President
Quirino called the Hardie Report a “national insult.” In 1953, Hardie was replaced by John
Cooper. Cooper suggested only minor
reforms were necessary in his report released in 1954. The overall mood was changing in the US, and
with the rise of McCarthyism, Ladejinsky, architect of land reform in Japan and
Taiwan, was accused of being a national security risk (Putzel 1992:91,
96-99). Once the US pressure for liberal
land reform disappeared, the landed oligarchy was easily able to preserve their
economic base through their representatives in Congress (Doronila
1992:102-104).
The Philippine
case shows that, without external threat or pressures, the repeated attempts
for land reform were unsuccessful because the state was captured by the
powerful landed class. In addition, the
failure of land reform helped the landed oligarchy to maintain and expand their
power continuously, and the economic policy machinery was routinely hijacked by
the powerful landed and business elites (MacIntyre 1994:9). By the early 1980s, a study identified 81
families as exercising extensive control over the economy. They also employed their wealth and power to
gain access to state positions either through appointment or election. Although popular demand for the
redistribution of land was always a main political issue, genuine reform never
occurred. The landowning elite could
employ a variety of official and unofficial means to protect their
interests. The militant landlords even
established private armies and allied with former Defense Minister Ponce
Enrile, when land reform became a more real issue after democratization. As a result, Aquino’s limited land reform was
only 30 percent completed by 1994, and did little to alter the distribution of
land in the Philippines (Moran 1999).
By contrast, land
reform had a huge impact on Korean society and the economy. Large landlords
virtually disappeared. Agricultural
productivity improved steadily (Ban, Moon, and Perkins 1980: 291-93). Land redistribution plus the destruction of
large private properties during the war produced an unusually equal
distribution of assets and income in Korea (Mason et al. 1980; You 1998). Indeed, land reform opened space for state
autonomy from the dominant class (Suh 1998).
As Rodrik (1995) noted, the initial advantage with respect to income and
wealth distribution in Korea and Taiwan is probably the single most important
reason why extensive government intervention could be carried out effectively,
without giving rise to rampant rent-seeking.
Land reform also
contributed to increasing enrollment in schools, by making it affordable to
more people. A characteristic of
post-war public education in Korea was an unusually large share of the
financial burden imposed on private households relative to other countries with
comparable enrollment (Mason et al. 1980).
The enrollment in primary schools doubled between 1945 and 1955, even
though the Korean War (1950-53) destroyed the whole country. The enrollment in secondary schools increased
more than 8 times over, and enrollment in colleges and universities increased
ten times during the same period (Kwon 1984).
The spectacular increase in an educated labor force not only made high
growth based on high productivity possible, but also paved the road for the
establishment of meritocratic bureaucracy.
Although the higher civil service exam (Haengsi) was instituted as early
as 1949, only 4 percent of those filling higher entrylevel positions came in
via the exam under Rhee Syngman’s government.
The higher positions were filled primarily through special appointments
(Evans 1995:51-52). This reflected not
only Rhee’s reliance on clientelistic ties but also a shortage of a pool of
enough highly educated people. Park
Chung-Hee, however, was able to establish meritocratic bureaucracy with the aid
of a supply of enough university-educated people, although he still allocated a
substantial part of the higher ranks to the military who did not pass the highly
competitive civil service exam.
Land reform in
Korea, however, had its limitations too.
It was restricted to farmland, while mountains and forests were excluded
(Chung 1967). Later, Korea came to
experience serious problems of land speculation, extremely high prices of land,
growing inequality in land ownership, and excessive generation of capital gain
from land ownership, which contributed to increasing income inequality (Lee
1991; Lee 1995).
Another question
regarding successful land reform in Korea and Taiwan is whether the
implementation processes were corrupt, and if so, why. In Korea, besides
redistribution of land, Rhee’s government carried out another distribution
program of former Japanese enterprises, which was known to be characterized by rampant
corruption (Woo 1991). It is also well
known that privatization processes in Russia and other East European countries
created enormous rents and corruption.
It is hard to find incidents of corruption from the implementation of
land reform, however.
The
implementation of land distribution was very transparent and participatory, in
Korea as well as in Taiwan and earlier in Japan. In Japan, Ladejinsky and his liberal
colleagues emphasized tenants’ participation in the implementation
process. Land Commissions were
established at national and local levels, and local committees were elected,
including five tenants, three landowners, and two owner-cultivators (Putzel
1992: 73). Korea and Taiwan followed the
Japanese example. In Korea, local
committees were comprised of one public official, three landowners, and three
tenants. A case study of local-level
implementation shows that the legal provisions were largely observed with minor
exceptions and without signs of corruption (Kwon 1984). Thus, the land reform case illustrates that
government intervention does not necessarily create corruption when it is
carried out in a transparent and participatory way.
Chaebol-centered
industrialization
A myth exists
about Park Chung-Hee’s economic development strategy. It is true that he tried to justify his
regime by rapid economic growth. It is
also true that his administration was more competent in setting economic
policies and implementing them effectively than the Rhee administration. It is a myth, however, that the Park
administration made the first five-year economic plan based on export-led
growth strategy, as Lie (1998:55-56) demonstrated. Actually, Park’s first five-year plan copied
much from the short-lived Chang Myun administration’s (1960-61) five-year
plan. Nor was Park’s first five-year
plan particularly export-oriented. It
emphasized the importance of import-substitution industrialization to fulfill
the goal of a “self-reliant economy.”
Its initial projection of export growth, mainly of agricultural produce
and raw materials, was modest. Park’s
emphasis on exports came later.[10]
The most
characteristic aspect of Park’s economic strategy was his emphasis on state
control of the economy and the promotion of large corporations and
conglomerates, or chaebols, apparently emulating Japanese zaibatsu. Although many chaebol began to form in the
1950s, their rapid growth occurred under Park’s patronage. For him, modernization and industrialization
meant emulating Japan. Later his Yushin
(1972) was very much modeled on the Meiji Restoration (1860) of Japan, and he
openly expressed his admiration for the leaders of the Meiji Restoration (Moran
1999).
Park’s
chaebol-centered industrialization strategy is contrasted with Taiwan’s
development strategy. Chiang Kai-Shek
had little interest in helping Taiwanese indigenous businesses grow too large,
because his power base was from those people who came from mainland China. The KMT leadership distanced itself from big
businesses, and pursued both growth and equity.
The KMT also adopted monetary conservatism, which made Taiwan’s
state-business relationship less close, direct, and deep than Korea’s. In addition, the KMT advocated state
ownership of strategic sectors. Unlike
Syngman Rhee who sold off former Japanese firms at a bargain price, Chiang
Kai-Shek transformed Taiwan’s enemy properties into state enterprises. As a result of monetary conservatism and
state ownership of strategic sectors, small-and-medium-sizedenterprises (SMEs)
grew and became the main force of the economy.
The number of manufacturing firms increased by 150 percent and the
average firm size grew by 29 percent between 1966 and 1976 in Taiwan, while in
Korea the number of firms increased by only 10 percent, though firm size grew
by 176 percent (Kim and Im 2001).
In order to both
control and support the chaebol, Park used selective allocation of low-interest
rate foreign loans and domestic loans through state-controlled banks. Virtually
all foreign loans (both public loans and private long-term loans) with low
interest rates required government approval and guarantee. The government controlled all commercial
banks and adopted a low-interest rate policy, which created large rents and
brought about a chronic shortage in the supply of loans. As Table 8 shows, the nominal bank rate was
typically less than half of the curb-market rate and the real bank rate was
often negative. Chaebol that began to
grow under the Rhee regime’s patronage through the allocation of aid dollars
and former Japanese enterprises were continuously supported by the Park regime
only if they paid back through economic performance such as exports and
unofficial political contributions. As a
result, the chaebol expanded rapidly, while most SMEs had difficulty in getting
loans and had to rely much more on the curb market. Thus, the collusion between politics and
business (chungkyungyoochak)—the triple alliance of the government, the
chaebol, and the banks—was gradually established (Lee 1995).
Table 8. Real and Nominal
Loan Rates, 1963-1976
Year Nominal Rate Curb Rate |
Inflation |
Real Rate |
|
1963 15.7 |
52.6 |
28.7 |
-13.0 |
1964 16.0 |
61.8 |
32.1 |
-16.1 |
1965 26.0 |
58.9 |
8.2 |
17.8 |
1966 26.0 |
58.7 |
14.3 |
11.7 |
1967 26.0 |
56.5 |
14.0 |
12.0 |
1968 25.8 |
56.0 |
11.8 |
14.0 |
1969 24.5 |
51.4 |
10.1 |
14.4 |
1970 24.0 |
49.8 |
13.2 |
10.8 |
1971 23.0 |
46.4 |
11.5 |
11.5 |
1972 17.7 |
39.0 |
14.5 |
3.2 |
1973 15.5 |
33.4 |
9.4 |
6.1 |
1974 15.5 |
40.6 |
26.7 |
-11.2 |
1975 15.5 |
41.3 |
24.1 |
-8.6 |
1976 17.5 |
n.a. |
15.7 |
1.8 |
Source: Jones and Sakong (1980:105)
Cultivating good
relationships with the President became a golden road for business expansion,
under Park Chung-Hee and Chun Doo-Whan in particular, and to a lesser degree,
under subsequent presidents as well.
Chung Ju-Young of Hyundai and Kim Woo-Jung of Daewoo had close personal
links with Park Chung-Hee and received extensive support (Moran 1999). Chung Ju-Young’s close ties to Park led the
media to dub Hyundai the “Yushin chaebol.”
On the other hand, Samhak, a major distillery and one of the largest
Korean conglomerates in the late 1960s, faced misfortune because the owner
backed Kim Dae-Jung in the 1971 presidential election. After the election, Samhak was convicted of
tax evasion and forced into bankruptcy (Lie 1998:90-91).
Another myth
about Park Chung-Hee is that his administration was coherent and autonomous,
while Rhee’s was incoherent and captured by businesses. Clearly, Park’s chaebol-centered
industrialization strategy was not a result of the chaebol’s lobby, but rather
was based on his own desire to emulate Japan’s industrialization. The chaebol’s share of the national economy
was small when Park seized power, because of land reform and the destruction of
private properties during the war. The
level of economic concentration was still relatively low during the 1970s in
comparison with other countries like Pakistan and India, although business
concentration was rapidly growing in Korea at that time (Jones and Sakong
1980:261-269). As economic concentration
by the chaebol grew, however, Park and subsequent regimes often found
themselves being effectively captured by them.
Although Park chose his business clients and the chaebol grew under his
patronage, he had to accommodate the chaebol’s demand for a bail-out when they
were in crisis. When big businesses
faced the threat of financial insolvency in 1971,[11] the Federation of Korean
Industrialists (FKI) requested that President Park freeze the curb, transfer
outstanding curb loans to official financial intermediaries, reduce the
corporate tax, and slash interest rates.
Park issued an Emergency Decree for Economic Stability and Growth, which
transformed curb market loans into bank loans to be repaid over five years at
lower interest rates, with a grace period of three years during which curb
market loans were to be frozen. To bail
out the overleveraged chaebol, the Emergency Decree shifted the burden to small
savers. Out of 209,896 persons who
registered as creditors, 70 percent were small lenders with assets in the
market below 1 million won, or $2,890 (Woo 1991: 109-115; Kim and Im).
Park encouraged
businesses to organize business associations, probably to make it easier to
control individual firms. Business
associations were, on the one hand, valuable and reliable sources of
information for state officials and thus facilitated collaboration between the
state and the business (Evans 1995; Schneider and Maxfield 1997). They also served as a conduit of raising
official funds like the National Security Fund as well as unofficial political
funds. For example, the FKI used to
allocate to the chaebol specific amounts of political donations and
contributions to the National Security Fund (Oh and Sim 1995). Business associations as well as the chaebol
became increasingly powerful, however, as the example of the successful
lobbying by the FKI for freezing the curb market demonstrates.
Senior government
officials often moved to corporate think tanks or to leadership positions in
business associations (Perkins 2000).
Although Schneider and Maxfield (1997) conjectured that the association
leaders were extensions of the economic bureaucracy rather than representatives
of the private sector, this view of the developmental state overlooks the
aspect of a growing tendency of capture and corruption. Although Korea’s developmental state never
degenerated into a hopeless degree of capture and corruption as in the
Philippines, the growing power of the chaebol increasingly became a great
concern for the public as well as for subsequent administrations.
When Chun
Doo-Whan came to power in 1980, he initially attempted to prosecute big
business on charges of illicit wealth accumulation, cut the collusion between
government and business, and introduce aggressive neo-liberal reforms. The FKI made an open statement that it was
not desirable to make big business a scapegoat in every regime change and that
preferential treatment of big business was not an act of corruption. At the same time, they made it clear that they
were willing to support and comply with the new government. Chun accepted the pledges of loyalty in
return for dropping the corruption charges as Park did in 1961.
In September
1980, however, Chun’s new government announced sweeping reforms to reduce
business concentration such as the forced sale of the chaebol’s “idle” real
estate and non-essential subsidiaries and tight credit control over big
business. Twenty-six of the largest
chaebol were instructed to sell off 166 subsidiaries (from a total of 631) and
to dispose of 459 tracts of idle land.
In the same vein, the Monopoly Regulation and Fair Trade Law was enacted
in April 1981. There was little progress
in reducing economic concentration during Chun’s presidency, however. The FKI openly opposed and lobbied against
the monopoly regulation law, tight credit controls, and industrial
rationalization. Although the chaebol
were forced to sell off a total of 166 subsidiaries in 1981, within four years
120 new subsidiaries were acquired.
Similarly, the chaebol acquired new land holdings worth 20 times more
than those they had sold off (Moon 1994).
Similar things
were repeated under the Roh Tae-Woo and Kim Young-Sam administrations. Like Chun, both Roh and Kim initially
attempted to implement some measures to reduce economic concentration,
primarily to improve public support. At
the end of each president’s five-year term, however, the chaebol ended up
increasing their size and power. In
particular, both Chun and Roh met frequently with heads of the chaebol
individually and received huge amount of unofficial political donations. When Roh had to run for the direct
presidential election, competing with Kim Young-Sam and Kim Dae-Jung, Chun was
known to have met with 30 heads of chaebol and collected 5 billion won from
each. Thus, he was easily able to raise funds, out of which he gave 100 billion
won to Roh (Oh and Sim 1995). Although
Kim Young-Sam is not known to have directly received political donations from the
chaebol during his presidency, he is known to have received 60 billion won from
Chung Tae-Soo, the head of the Hanbo group, when he was competing with Kim
Dae-Jung in the 1992 presidential election (Woo 1991:60). Thus, reform of the chaebol was not pursued
with vigor and was effectively abandoned in exchange for illegal political
donations.
As Table 9 shows,
economic concentration by the chaebol increased over time, and the really
vigorous measures for reform of the chaebol did not occur until Korea was hit
by a financial crisis and had to be bailed out by the IMF. Park’s chaebol-centered industrialization
strategy produced not only corruption and collusion between the government and
the chaebol but also increasingly created inefficiencies and widened inequality. It is well known that the collapse of
overleveraged chaebol like Hanbo in 1997 and the excessive short-term debt of
the chaebol from foreign banks was one main reason why Korea became a victim of
the Asian financial crisis, while Taiwan was little affected by the crisis. In fact, the inefficiencies of the “chaebol
economy” and the risks of overleveraged chaebol that became evident to everyone
after 1997 were manifest much earlier.
As early as 1980, Korean manufacturers had an average debt equity ratio
of 488 percent, while this ratio remained below 200 percent in Taiwan (Kim and
Im 2001).
Table 9. Trends in Chaebol Concentration, 1985-95
(Cumulative percent
for manufacturing industry) (unit:%)
# chaebol |
#
employees |
sales |
|
value added |
assets |
|
||
|
1985 |
1990 |
1995 |
1985 1990 |
1995 |
1985
1990 1995 |
1985 1990 |
1995 |
4 |
6.5 |
6.9 |
8.1 |
21.9 23.4 |
27.3 |
11.7
17 27.2 |
23.6 26 |
28 |
10 |
8.2 |
9 |
10.7 |
33.5 32.6 |
37.2 |
16.5 22.8 29.3 |
33.3 36.5 |
39.5 |
30 |
11.6 |
11.7 |
13.1 |
43.1 40.6 |
44.9 |
22.2
29 41 |
45.6 46.8 |
50.2 |
Source: Cho (1997)
The 1971 bail-out
of big businesses, done at the expense of a large number of small creditors,
signaled that the state would not be able to let a big business fail if only it
is big enough for its failure to give the national economy an intolerable
shock. Because the interest rate of the state-controlled banks was always much
lower than the market interest rate, the chaebol had an incentive to
over-invest, relying on over-borrowing.
When the size of the national economy was relatively small, the state
could coordinate investments and prevent redundant and excessive
investments. As the national economy as
well as the size of the chaebol grew, the coordination became more and more
difficult and inefficiencies grew.
The Chaebol’s
investments were not limited to productive ones. One serious problem was the land speculation
of the chaebol. The overexpansion of
large cities in the 1970s brought about a land shortage, which forced up the
price of land and housing (Suh 1998:26). The chaebol purchased large areas of
land not for productive but for speculative purposes with the low-interest bank
loans. Because the price of land
increased much faster than average prices of other goods, it was a very
profitable investment for the chaebol.
Five percent of landowners owned 65 percent of private land in 1989, and
their share increased to 83 percent in 2004 (Hangyoreh Sinmun 07-15-2005).
Chaebol-centered industrialization increased the inequality of
income and wealth.
The Gini index rose during the
1970s, fell a little in the 1980s, but rose again in the 1990s. In particular, income inequality has been
continuously increasing after the financial crisis of 1997 (Lee Forthcoming;
Yoo and Kim 2002). Lee (1991) shows that
increasing inequality in land ownership and capital gains from land ownership
contribute significantly to income inequality, although official income
statistics fail to capture this. He
estimates that unearned income from transactions of land accounted for 10-20
percent of GDP in the late 1980s. While
the Gini index based on official income statistics was 33.6 in 1988, it was as
high as 38.6 including capital gains from land, and 41.2 including capital
gains from shares as well as land, according to his estimates. Although land reform contributed to an
unusually low income inequality, it was restricted to farmland. Land speculation of the rich and the chaebol
increasingly concentrated land ownership and worsened income distribution.
In summary,
chaebol industrialization increased income inequality and wealth concentration
over time, and the balance of power has shifted. Those in political power and the chaebol
exchanged favors, such as under-priced credit allocation and political
donation. Although the state had a
dominant position in the early period, the chaebol’s ability to buy political
influence increased and the state was increasingly captured by the chaebol due
to corruption and the logic of “too big to fail.”
Democratization
and the development of civil society
The role of
democratization and democracy in controlling corruption is not simple. Democratization has both positive and
negative impacts on controlling corruption.
Competitive elections and the growth of civil society can be a check on
corrupt politicians, but the need to finance expensive election campaigns
creates new incentives for corruption.
Moreover, the exposure of corruption and media reports are likely to
increase with improvement of the freedom of the press, which may cause
perceptions of corruption to rise even though actual corruption has not risen
(Rose-Ackerman 1999).
As I earlier
indicated in Table 3, the trend of the CPI shows corruption became lower under
Kim Young-Sam (1993-97: CPI of 4.3), Kim Dae-Jung (1998-2002: CPI of 4.2), and
Roh Moo-Hyun (2003-04: CPI of 4.8) than under Chun Doo-Whan (1981-87: CPI of
3.9) and Roh Tae-Woo (1988-92: CPI of 3.5).
If the CPI trend reflects reality, the positive effect of
democratization on controlling corruption was not realized immediately but
several years after democratization began in 1987.
Although Roh
Tae-Woo (1988-92) was elected president in a democratic election, thanks to a
split of votes between two former democratization fighters, Kim Dae-Jung and
Kim Young-Sam, he was the second man in the 1980 military coup and Chun’s pick
as his successor. His anti-corruption
campaign never gained public confidence, and he turned out to be no less
corrupt than Chun. As the need to
finance expensive election campaigns creates new incentives for corruption
(Rose-Ackerman 1999).
Kim Young-Sam
(1993-97) was the first civilian President after Rhee, although his former
Party for Unification and Democracy merged with Roh Tae-Woo’s Democratic
Justice Party and thus was supported by former military political power. Kim
Young-Sam launched an extensive anti-corruption drive, which was regarded as
genuine by the general public. He
declared he would not receive any money as president unlike his predecessors,
and introduced reforms such as the disclosure of assets by high-level public
officials, the real-name financial transaction system, and amendments of the
Election Malpractice Prevention Act and the Political Fund Law. The 1995 local elections were generally
assessed to be very clean with a marked decline in practices of vote-buying,
but the ruling party was decisively defeated (Oh 1999). In the 1996 national assembly elections, Kim
Young-Sam seemed to be more interested in the results of the election than in
fair and clean processes.
Between the 1995
local elections and the 1996 national assembly elections, two former
Presidents, Chun Doo-Whan and Roh Tae-Woo, were arrested and indicted on
charges of corruption as well as mutiny and treason, and their trial
began. Chun and Roh were sentenced to
death and 22.5 years in prison, respectively, in August 1996 (Oh 1999). They were later given presidential pardons
with the agreement between Kim Young-Sam and Kim Dae-Jung just after Kim
Dae-Jung was elected President in the midst of the financial crisis in December
1997.
Although Kim
Young-Sam’s anti-corruption drive reached a peak with the indictment of Chun
and Roh, the 1996 national elections revealed his political will to root out
corruption had been compromised by his will to win. The Hanbo corruption scandal and its
bankruptcy in 1997 revealed not only the weakness of the chaebol-centered
economy but also corrupt relations between the chaebol and the political elite
including Kim Young-Sam’s son. Later, it
was revealed that Kim Young-Sam himself had received 60 billion won in
donations from Chung Tae-Soo of Hanbo in 1992 and that around 100 billion won
of illegal funds were used in the 1996 National Assembly elections when he was
president.
Kim Dae-Jung
(1998-2002) was the first president in Korean history who was elected as an
opposition candidate. With the economic
crisis, public sentiment was very critical of the chaebol and the collusion
between government and the chaebol, and public expectations for anti-corruption
reform was high. Unlike those of Kim
Young-Sam, the reforms of Kim Dae-Jung were more focused on enhancing autonomy
of banks and transparency of the chaebol than purging corrupt politicians. James Schopf (2001) demonstrates that Korea
experienced a noticeable drop in bank-based corruption from the dictatorial
Chun regime, where low-interest bank loans were exchanged for bribes, to the
democratic Kim Dae-Jung government, which severed the link between political
leaders and bank presidents through bank management reform. As with Kim Young-Sam, however, Kim
Dae-Jung’s sons were found to be involved in corruption scandals.
Roh Moo-Hyun
(2003-2007) obtained the party’s nomination through caucuses and primaries with
a relatively small campaign fund. He
largely relied on small donations through the internet and grassroots mobilization
for his campaign fund for the presidential election, and defeated the
conservative candidate, Lee Hoi-Chang, who was later found to be illegally
funded by the chaebol. Roh Moo-Hyun was
not perfectly free from illegal funds, and his aids were prosecuted together
with Lee Hoi-Chang’s campaign fundraisers.
Samsung Group was found to have made an illegal contribution of 34
billion won to Lee and 3 billion won to Roh in the 2002 presidential election
(PSPD 2005). The National Assembly
elections in April 2004 were seen as relatively clean.
No less
important, an anti-corruption campaign came from civil society. Civil society organizations launched a
“campaign for fair and clean elections” starting in 1991, and it is believed
that it contributed considerably to monitoring politicians and to increasing
public awareness. Civil society
organizations upgraded their movement in 2000.
They released a list of corrupt politicians and launched negative
campaigns to defeat them.
Seventy percent of those candidates
on the black list of CSOs were defeated in the National Assembly elections of
April 2000 (You 2003).
The trend of the
CPI seems to reflect reality to a certain degree. The CPI was highest in 1995 (4.3) and 1996
(5.0) after Kim Young-Sam’s extensive anti-corruption drive. The relatively low scores of the CPI in 1997
(4.3), 1998 (4.2), and 1999 (3.8) seem to reflect partly the corruption
scandals such as Hanbo’s that occurred in 1997 and partly the perceptions of
crony capitalism by the international community after the financial crisis of
1997. The gradually increasing CPI
scores in recent years from 3.8 in 1999 to 5.1 in 2006 and 2007 may reflect
various reform measures taken during this period and recovery from the
perception of “crony capitalism” as Korea has recovered from the economic
crisis.
There are some
promising signs in recent years. Some surveys indicate that corruption has been
slightly declining recently. The annual
surveys of the Korea Independent Commission Against Corruption (KICAC) show
that the percentage of clients that bribe public officials by money or
entertainment has been declining from 4.1 percent in 2002, to 3.5 percent in
2003, to 1.5 percent in 2004. Public
opinion surveys conducted in 1996 and 2003 show that the Korean people are
increasingly intolerant of corruption, as Table 10 indicates.
Table 10. Public Opinion
about the Acceptability of Bribery
|
To a traffic policeman |
To a teacher |
To a public official |
||
<Survey year> |
1996 2003 |
1996 |
2003 |
1996 |
2003 |
Strongly oppose |
36.2 61.9 |
55.9 |
66.8 |
44.6 |
71.0 |
Somewhat oppose |
23.8 17.3 |
19.7 |
14.8 |
27.3 |
15.4 |
Uncertain |
26.1 17.6 |
15.4 |
14.8 |
20.5 |
9.9 |
Somewhat acceptable |
11.9 3.0 |
7.9 |
3.1 |
6.1 |
3.3 |
Very acceptable |
1.8 0.3 |
0.8 |
0.6 |
0.8 |
0.3 |
Sources: Lim (1996) and Park (2003). |
It seems that
Korea is slowly reducing corruption, although it is too early to tell with
certainty. In the earlier period of
democratization, the corrupting effect due to the increasing demand for
political funds seemed to be stronger than the anti-corruption effect due to
enhanced monitoring and accountability mechanisms. Democratic reforms and the growth of civil
society, however, seem to increasingly play a positive role in curbing
corruption. Many Koreans hope that the
practice of huge amounts (billions of won) of illegal political contributions
by the chaebol will subside in the future, but it is yet to be seen whether new
practices of transparent financing of political funds will be firmly
established.[12]
Conclusion
Among the
conventionally accepted causes of corruption, only income inequality is
significantly correlated with corruption among the three countries of Korea,
Taiwan, and the Philippines, consistent with the finding of the cross-national
statistical study of You and Khagram (2005).
Further analysis reveals that land reform in Korea and Taiwan dissolved
the landed elite and produced an unusually equal initial distribution of income
and wealth, which helped prevent the state apparatus from being hopelessly captured
by a powerful class. Corruption was not
a main factor that determined the success or failure of land reform, and
external factors played more important roles. Thus, land reform was exogenously
given to Korea and Taiwan, where landlords lost political power because of
their collaboration with the Japanese colonial rule and there was urgency for
reform because of imminent communist threats.
In the Philippines, however, there was not such urgency for reform for
both domestic politics and the US, and the landed elite were able to resist the
reform successfully. Consequently, the
level of inequality and corruption in Korea and Taiwan has been much lower than
that in the Philippines.
Although it is hard to compare the level of corruption before and
after land reform in
Korea because the
government immediately prior to the reform was the American
Military Government, some observers
report that corruption decreased substantially after the reform in Taiwan
(Putzel 1992). In contrast, in the
Philippines, the failure of land reform maintained the power of the landed
oligarchy and led to high inequality in income and wealth: the landed and
business elites were able to capture the state, and continuous redistributive
pressures for land forced the politicians to repeatedly promise land reform and
the landlords to increasingly rely on corruption.
Although both
Korea and Taiwan enjoyed exceptionally high equality initially largely due to
land reform, Korea’s chaebol-centered industrialization policies increased
income inequality and encouraged rent-seeking and corruption at the same
time. In contrast, Taiwan’s monetary
conservatism and SME-centered industrialization did not encourage rent-seeking
and moral hazard. Thus, Korea’s level of
corruption has become a little higher than that of Taiwan. Again, corruption did not much affect the
initial choice of different industrialization strategies, but different
government policies had a large impact on corruption, efficiency, and
inequality.
This study
suggests that economic growth is a consequence rather than a cause of
corruption. Inequality affected the
level of corruption and capture, which in turn determined economic growth. Thus, corruption is likely to be an important
channel through which inequality adversely affects economic growth. Although Alesina and Rodrik (1994) and
Persson and Tabellini (1994) argue that the adverse effect of inequality on
economic growth is attributable to high rates of taxation and redistribution,
my findings suggest an alternative explanation, with corruption as a causal
pathway. The Philippine case
demonstrates that inequality does not necessarily cause redistribution. Inequality created redistributive demand, but
the wealthy employed corruption and capture to avoid or minimize
redistribution.
This paper also
shows that government intervention does not necessarily increase
corruption. Some kinds of government
intervention increase inequality and corruption at the same time. The sale of Japanese vested properties and a
low interest rate credit allocation are such examples. Redistribution of farmland did not produce
corruption, however, because it was implemented in a transparent and
participatory way. The extensive state
ownership of big corporations in Taiwan did not create much corruption, while
favoring big conglomerates in Korea did create much corruption. Thus, the policy implication of this study is
that simply linking the extent of government intervention or the size of government
to corruption is too naïve and that the kind of intervention and the method of
implementation should be considered.
In summary, this
comparative historical analysis not only supports my argument for the causal
effect of inequality on corruption, but also shows through what mechanisms different
levels of income and wealth inequality due to exogenous shocks (land reform and
industrial policy) affected corruption.
The causal mechanisms identified by this paper are: (1) higher inequality (due to failure of land
reform) ® stronger redistributive pressures ® greater
incentives and resources for corruption, (2) lower inequality (due to land
reform) ® more equal opportunity for education ® meritocratic
bureaucracy ® lower corruption, and (3) certain government interventions
(under-priced credit rationing for the chaebol) ® higher
inequality and corruption at the same time.
Regarding the
democracy effect, the Korean case illustrates both a corrupting effect due to
political financing needs and an anti-corruption effect to due to enhanced
monitoring and accountability mechanisms.
Increasing income inequality and economic concentration by the chaebol
are continuing concerns, while the positive effect of democratic reforms is a
promising sign for Korea.
NOTES
Ades, Alberto and
Rafael Di Tella. 1999. "Rents, Competition and Corruption." American
Economic Review 89:982–94.
Alesina, Alberto F.,
Arnaud Devleeschauwer, William Easterly, Sergio Kurlat, and Romain Wacziarg.
2003. "Fractionalization." Journal of Economic Growth 8:155–94.
Alesina, Alberto F.
and Dani Rodrik. 1994. "Distributive Politics and Economic Growth."
Quarterly Journal of Economics 109:465–90.
Amsden, Alice. 1989.
Asia’s Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Ban, Sung Hwan, P.Y. Moon, and D. Perkins. 1980. Rural Development:
Studies in the Modernization of The Republic of Korea: 1945-1975. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press.
Booth, Anne. 1999.
“Initial Conditions and Miraculous Growth: Why is South East Asia Different
From Taiwan and South Korea?” World Development 27(2):301-321.
Cho, Tong-Sung.
1997. Hankuk Chaebol (Korean Chaebol). Seoul: Maeil Kyongje Sinmunsa.
Chun, Sang-In.
2001. “Migunjonggiui Nongop Munjewa Toji Chongchaek (Agricultural
Problems and Land Policy under the American Military Government).”
In Hong, SongChan ed., Nongji Kaehyok Yongu (Studies in Agrarian Land Reform).
Seoul: Yonsei University Press.
Chung, Young-Il. 1967. “Chonhu Hanguk Nongji Kaehyoke Kwanhan Il
Kochal (A Review of Post-War Agrarian Reform in Korea).” Kyongje Nonjip (Korean
Economic Journal) 6(2): 77-112.
Dollar, David and
Aart Kraay. 2002. “Growth is Good for the Poor.” Journal of Economic Growth 7:
195-225. Data available at:
http://econ.worldbank.org/view.php?type=18&id=22018.
Doronila, Amando.
1992. The State, Economic Transformation, and Political Change in the
Philippines, 1946-1972. Singapore: Oxford University Press.
Evans, Peter. 1995.
Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Friedman, Eric, Simon Johnson, Daniel Kaufmann, and Pablo
Zoido-Lobaton. 2000. "Dodging the Grabbing Hand: The Determinants of
Unofficial Activity in 69 Countries." Journal of Public Economics
76:459–93.
Fukuyama, Francis.
1995. Trust: The Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity. Free Press, New
York
Fukuyama, Francis.
2000. “Asian Values, Korean Values, and Democratic
Consolidation.” In
Larry Diamond and Doh Chull Shin eds., Institutional Reform and Democratic
Consolidation in Korea, Stanford CA: Hoover Institution Press.
Hahn, Bae-ho. 1975. “The Authority Structure of Korean Politics.” In
Edward Reynolds Wright ed., Korean Politics in Transition, pp.289-301, Seattle:
University of Washington Press.
Heston, Alan, Robert
Summers, and Bettina Aten. 2002. Penn World Table Version 6.1. Center for
International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania (CICUP).
Hong, Song-Chan. “Nongji Kaehyok Chonhuui Taejiju Tonghyang
(Responses of the Landlords before and after the Land Reform).” In Hong,
Song-Chan ed., Nongji Kaehyok Yongu (Studies in Agrarian Land Reform). Seoul:
Yonsei University Press.
Hutchcroft, Paul. 1994. “Booty Capitalism: Busines-Government
Relations in the Philippines.” In Andrew MacIntyre ed., Business and Government
in Industrializing Asia. St. Leonards, Australia: Allen & Unwin Pty
Ltd.
Iversen, Torben and David Soskice. 2002. Electoral Systems and the
Politics of Coalitions: Why Some Democracies Redistribute More than Others.
Paper presented at the 2002 annual meetings of American Political Science
Association. Available at:
http://www.people.fas.harvard.edu/~iversen/Iversen-Soskice2003.pdf. Accessed on
08/01/2003.
Johnson, Chalmers.
1982. MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy,
1925-1975. Stanford University Press.
Johnston, Michael. 1989.
"Corruption, Inequality, and Change." Pp. 13–37 in Corruption,
Development and Inequality, edited by P. Ward. London and New York:
Routledge.
Jones, Leroy P. and
Il Sakong. 1980. Government, Business, and Entrepreneurship in Economic
Development: The Korean Case. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Kang, David C. 2002.
Crony Capitalism: Corruption and Development in South Korea and the
Philippines. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Kaufmann, Daniel and Aart Kraay. 2002. "Growth Without
Governance." World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2928. Available
at: http://econ.worldbank.org/docs/1199.pdf.
Kaufmann, D., A.
Kraay, and M. Mastruzzi. 2003. Governance Matters III: Governance Indicators
for 1996–2002. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3106.
Washington, DC:
World Bank. Available at:
http://econ.worldbank.org/files/28791_wps3106.pdf.
Kim, Byung-Kook and
Im, Hyug-Baeg. 2001. “Crony Capitalism in South Korea, Thailand and Taiwan:
Myth and Reality.” Journal of East Asian Studies 1(2): 5-52.
Kim, Jin-Bae and
Park, Chang-Rae. 1968. “CHAGWAN (Foreign Loans).” Sin Tonga December 1968.
Kim, Jin-Hyon. 1964. “Pujong Chukjae Chori Chonmalso (A Report of
Details of the Investigation and Punishment on the Corruptly Accumulated
Wealth). Sin Tonga December 1964: 158-177.
Kim, Kyong-Il. 1999.
Gongjagarul Jukoya Naraga Sanda (Kill Confucius, and the Nation will prosper).
Seoul: Bada Press.
Kim, Sung-Bo. 2001.
“Ipbopkwa Silhaeng Kwajongul Tonghae Bon Namhan Nongji
Kaehyokui Songkyok (The Characteristics of South Korea’s Land Reform
Based on Legislative and Implementation Processes).” In Hong, Song-Chan ed.,
Nongji Kaehyok Yongu (Studies in Agrarian Land Reform). Seoul: Yonsei
University Press.
Klitgaard, Robert.
1988. Controlling Corruption. Berkeley, CA: University of California
Press.
Krueger, Anne.
1984. “Political Economy of Rent Seeking Society.”
Kwon, Byung-Tak. 1984. “Nongji Kaehyokui Kwajongkwa Kyongjejok Kiyo
(Processes of Farmland Reform and Its Economic Contribution in Korea).” Nongop
Chongchaek Yongu (Korean Journal of Agricultural Policy) 11(1): 191-207.
Lamba, S. K. and J. S. Tomar. 1986. Impact of Land Reforms on Rural
Development: A Critical Appraisal of India, Republic of China and Some Other
Selected Countries. New Dehli, India: Agricole Publishing Academy.
La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Schleifer, and
Robert W. Vishny. 1999. "The Quality of Government." Journal of Law,
Economics and Organization 15:222–79.
Lee, Joung-woo. 1991. “Hankukui Pu, Chabon Idukkwa Soduk
Pulpyongdung (Wealth, Capital Gain, and Income Inequality in Korea).” KYONGJE
NONJIP (Economic Essays) 30(3):327-62.
Lee, Joung-woo.
Forthcoming. “Roadmap of Social Solidarity: Growth with Distribution.” Korea
Policy Review.
Lee, Jin-Soon. 1995. Kyongje Kaehyokron (Economic Reform). Seoul:
Bibong Publishing. Lee, Woong-Hee and
Kim, Chin-Hyon. 1964. “Chongchi Chagum (Political Funds).” Sin Tonga September
1964: 108-133.
Lie, John. 1998. Han
Unbound: The Political Economy of South Korea. Stanford, CA: Stanford
University Press.
Lim, Hyon-Jin. 1996. Chonhwangi Hankuk Sahoi Kukmin Uisikkwa Kachikwane
Kwanhan Chosa Yonku (Survey of Values and Ideas of the People in Korea’s
Changing Society). Available at http://www.kossda.or.kr.
MacIntyre, Andrew. 1994. “Business, Government and Development:
Northeast and Southeast Asian Comparisons.” In Andrew MacIntyre ed., Business
and Government in Industrializing Asia. St. Leonards, Australia: Allen &
Unwin Pty Ltd.
Mason, Edward S.,
Mahn Je Kim, Dwight H. Perkins, Kwang Suk Kim, and David C.
Cole with Leroy Jones, Il Sakong, Donald R. Snodgrass, and Noel F.
McGinn. 1980. The Economic and Social Modernization of the Republic of Korea.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Mauro, Paolo. 1995.
"Corruption and Growth." Quarterly Journal of Economics
110:681–712.
Meltzer, Allan H.
and Scott F. Richard. 1981. "A Rational Theory of the Size of
Government." Journal of Political Economy 89:914–27.
Montinola, G. and R.
Jackman. 2002. "Sources of Corruption: A Cross-Country Study."
British Journal of Political Science 32:147–70.
Moran, Jon. 1999.
“Patterns of Corruption and Development in East Asia.” Third World Quarterly
20(3):569-87.
Moon, Chung-in. 1994. “Changing Patterns of Business-Government
Relations in South Korea.” In Andrew MacIntyre ed., Business and Government in
Industrializing Asia. St. Leonards, Australia: Allen & Unwin Pty Ltd.
Oh, John Kie-chang.
1999. Korean Politics: The Quest for Democratization and Economic Development.
Cornell University Press.
Oh, Dae-young and
Sim, Sang-min. 1995. Hankukui Chiha Kyongje (Underground Economy of Korea).
Seoul: Miraesa.
Paldam, M. 2002.
"The Cross-Country Pattern of Corruption: Economics, Culture, and the
Seesaw Dynamics." European Journal of Political Economy 18:215–40.
Park, Kyong-Sok.
1967. “Taetongnyong, Kukhoiuiwon, Songo Chagum (The President, National
Assemblymen, and Campaign Funds).” Sin Tonga May 1967: 202-214.
Park, Myoung-Kyoo.
2003. Kukminui Kachikwankwa Uisike Taehan Chosa (Survey of Values and Ideas of
the Korean People). Available at http://www.kossda.or.kr.
Perkins, Dwight. 2000. “Law, Family Ties, and the East Asian Way of
Business.” In Harrison, Lawrence E. and Samuel P. Huntington eds., Culture
Matters: How Values Shape Human Progress. New York: Basic Books.
People’s Solidarity
for Participatory Democracy (Chamyo Yondae). 2005. “Samsung Group Ui Pulbop
Chongchi Chagumui Yoksawa Sabop Chori Hyonhwang (The History
of Samsung Group’s
Ilegal Political Donations and Legal Punishments).” http://www.peoplepower21.org/article/article_print.php?article_id=14233
Persson, Torsten and
Guido Tabellini. 1994. "Is Inequality Harmful for Growth?" American
Economic Review 84:600–21.
Putzel, James. 1992.
A Captive Land: The Politics of Agrarian Reform in the Philippines. London, UK:
Catholic Institute for International Relations.
Rodrik, Dani. 1995.
“Getting Interventions Right: How South Korea and Taiwan Grew Rich.” Economic
Policy 20 (April 1995): 55-107.
Rose-Ackerman,
Susan. 1999. Corruption and Government: Causes, Consequences and Reform.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Rueschemeyer,
Dietrich and John D. Stephens. 1997. “Comparing Historical SequencesA Powerful
Tool for Causal Analysis” Comparative Social Research 16: 55-72.
Sandholtz, W. and W.
Koetzle. 2000. "Accounting for Corruption: Economic Structure, Democracy,
and Trade." International Studies Quarterly 44:31–50.
Schneider and Maxfield. 1997. “Business, the State, and Economic
Performance in Developing Countries.” In Maxfield, S. and B. R. Schneider eds.,
Business and the State in Developing Countries. Ithaca and London: Cornell
University Press.
Schopf, James C.
2001. “An Explanation for the End of Political Bank Robbery in the Republic of
Korea: The T + T Model.” Asian Survey 41(5): 693–715.
Suh, Moon-Gi. 1998.
Developmental Transformation in South Korea: From Statesponsored Growth to the
Questfor Quality of Life. Westport, CT: Praeger Publishers.
Taylor, Charles
Lewis and David A. Jodice. 1983. World Handbook of Political and Social
Indicators. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Transparency International. Corruption Perceptions Index (CPI).
Berlin, Germany: Transparency International. Available at:
www.transparency.org/cpi/ index.html#cpi and
wwwuser.gwdg.de/~uwvw/corruption.cpi_2003.html.
Treisman, Daniel.
2000. "The Causes of Corruption: A Cross National Study." Journal of
Public Economics 76:399–457.
Tu, Weiming. 2001.
“The Ecological Turn in New Confucian Humanism: Implications for China and the
World.” Daedulus 130(4): 243-264.
Wade, Robert. 1990.
Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian
Industrialization. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Wedeman, Andrew. 1997. “Looters, Rent-Scrapers, and Dividend
Collectors: Corruption and Growth in Zaire, South Korea, and the Philippines.”
The Journal of Developing Areas 31(Summer): 457-478.
Woo, Jung-en. 1991.
Race to the Swift: State and Finance in Korean Industrialization. New York:
Columbia University Press.
World Bank. 1993.
The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy. A World Bank Policy
Research Report. New York: Oxford University Press.
Yee, Jaeyeol. 2000.
“The Social Networks of Koreans.” Korea Journal 40(1): 325-352.
Yoo, Kyung-joon and Dae-il Kim. 2002. “An Analysis of Changes in
Income Distribution and Impact of Redistribution Policy after the Foreign
Currency Crisis.” Korea Development Institute. KDI Research Report
2002-08.
Yoon, Tae-beom.
1994. “Kwanryo Pupae Hyongsonge Issoso Kyongjejok Chabyole
TTarun Simin Kaeibe Kwanhan Yonku (A Study of Citizen Involvement by
Economic Inequality in the Formation of Bureaucratic Corruption).” Hankuk
Haengjong Hakpo (Korean Public Administration Review) 28(1): 169-186.
You, Jong-il. 1998.
“Income Distribution and Growth in East Asia.” Journal of Development Studies
34(6): 37-65.
You, Jong-sung. 2003. “The Role of Civil Society in Combating
Corruption in South Korea.” Paper presented at the International
Anti-Corruption Conference, Seoul, May 2003.
You, Jong-sung and
Sanjeev Khagram. 2005. "A Comparative Study of Inequality and
Corruption." American Sociological Review 70 (1): 136-157.
[1] See Table 1 and the discussion on page 8 for the evidence.
[2] The perceptions of the domestic public concerning the extent of
corruption (World Values Survey, 1995– 97) have a correlation coefficient of
0.85 with the CCI and 0.86 with the CPI.
[3] According to a different social survey conducted in Korea in 2003,
5.4 percent (sometimes 5.0 percent, and frequently 0.4 percent) of Koreans had
some experience of bribing (Park 2003).
It is strikingly close to the 6 percent response from the Global
Barometer Survey.
[4] Bribery 04’s correlation with the CPI 02 and CCI 02 are -0.72 and
-0.73, respectively.
[5] The values of the historical data such as CPI 80-85 and CPI 88-92
are not strictly comparable to the values of CPI for later years, because there
are differences in the underlying survey data and their methods. So, looking at the relative rankings of the
three countries will be safer.
[6] Yushin refers to the pro-government coup by which Park eliminated
direct presidential elections and term limits and thereby made his power
permanent.
[7] Samsung gave Roh Moo-Hyun 3 billion won (2 billion won in 1990
constant prices) in 2002 (PSPD 2005). Samsung is known to have given some money
to Kim Dae-Jung, but the amount is still unknown (Hangyoreh Sinmun 07-25-2005).
[8] Kim Young-sam declared that he would not receive any money from the
business during his presidency. Hanbo’s illegal contribution to Kim Young-sam
was made in the presidential election year.
[9] It is hard to tell if this represents the real improvement in
controlling corruption because TI’s historical CPI for 1988-1992 is not
strictly comparable to the annual CPIs of 1995-2007. If we compare the rankings of these countries
with other countries, however, we can say the level of corruption has not
increased, if nor decreased, in these countries after democratization compared
to other countries.
[10] Rodrik (1995) raised doubt about export orientation as a key
explanation for economic growth in Korea and Taiwan, noting that the initial
size of exports was too small to have a significant effect on aggregate economic
performance.
[11] Because of the IMF pressure after the first debt crisis of 1969,
Park had to implement tough stabilization policies. As a result, the chaebol could not obtain
bank loans as easily as before and had to rely on the high-interest curb market
substantially.
[12] The recent Samsung slush fund scandal shows that such old practices
have not disappeared, but the special prosecution of the scandal could help end
such practices of chaebol.
No comments:
Post a Comment